2.3.Equity in the distribution of income

Syllabus Content

  • The meaning of equity in the distribution of income
  • Indicators of income equality and income inequality
  • Poverty
  • The role of taxation in promoting equity
  • Other measures to promote equity
  • The relationship between equity and efficiency

Introduction to Income Inequality

The meaning of equity in the distribution of income

Explain the difference between equity in the distribution of income and equality in the distribution of income.

Equity in economics is a concept meaning ‘fairness’ and ‘justice’, for example, that everybody should have the same right to work, own property and start a company – regardless of gender, ethnicity etc. There would then be fairness in the distribution of output, e.g. a just proportion of wealth to each and every citizen. Equality, on the other hand, would mean that everyone would have the same ability to work, own property and start a company – all would get equal portions of the wealth created.

Definition: “equity”

The concept of equity in economics deals with the highly normative concept of fairness in the distribution of wealth and income. Most countries have customs, laws and traditions aimed at giving disadvantaged members of society ‘fair shares’.

Definition: “equality”

Equality deals with spreading wealth and income equally, regardless of position or income in society.

The concept of equity is naturally highly normative and will therefore vary greatly over time and between cultures. There different moral and ethical bases in societies. In line with these differences, governments attempt to create equity, which is to say ‘everybody should have the same chance of bettering his or her situation’. Economics must often deal with the questions of equity:

 _Should the rich be taxed proportionately more than the poor and middle-classed? Should they pay more for university education?

 _Is it better to tax consumption (value-added taxes, VAT, for example) or income (taxes on profits and dividends)?

 _To what extent should the socially/economically disadvantaged be given additional resources at the expense of the economically advantaged – i.e. transfers of income and wealth aimed at evening-out income disparities?

 _What about the viewpoint of the wealthy; is it not an economic fact that the goods and services we desire are better furthered by self-interest and the profit motives of firms? Is it more economically efficient to increase output rather than re-distribute it? Should not governments try to create a favourable environment for firms and a framework for enterprise in order to increase the cake from which all subsequent taxes and income transfers will be sliced? Wouldn’t society ultimately gain if the incentives to produce (say via low corporate taxes) were enhanced?

Explain that due to unequal ownership of factors of production, the market system may not result in an equitable distribution of income.

Failure of market system

The above examples are but a small portion of a reoccurring debate within both economics and politics, dealing with the desirability and efficiency of government intervention in matters of equity. We have returned to the issues outlined in production possibility curves earlier, but now with a slightly more ideological and thus political flavour. The appealing simplicity of ‘invest now in order to produce more in the future’ must be appended by realism: it is not at all certain that any part of ‘more’ will be distributed equitably or evenly. Our basic economic problem is not so basic after all. If output were to grow by 50% and go to 0.1% of the population then we would certainly face some sort of sharp societal reaction – from protest lists to burning tyres in front of parliament. Most countries will have a redistribution system built into government policy, which evens out income differentials to a certain extent. Governments can redistribute income in three basic ways; taxation, transfer payments and goods and services in kind. (See further on.)

Source - http://goodbadecon.com/uploads/3/1/1/6/3116093/ch_55_-_equity_and_distr_of_income_-_2.3.pdf

Equity vs Equality

Indicators of income equality and income inequality

Changes in the position of the Lorenz Curve indicates changes in the distribution of income. In this example, the curve for 2010 is further away from the line of equal distribution than the curve in 1990, implying a wider distribution of income.

Explain how the Gini coefficient is derived and interpreted.

Gini coefficient: A Gini coefficient is a summary numerical measure of how unequally one variable is related to another. The Gini coefficient is a number between 0 and 1.

· Perfect equality has a Gini coefficient of zero.

· Absolute inequality yields a Gini coefficient of 1.

This Lorenz curve illustrates the degree of inequality in the distribution of income. A Gini coefficient can be calculated using areas on this Lorenz curve. The 45 degree line would reflect absolutely even distribution of income.

The pink shaded area A between the line of perfect equality and Lorenz curve reflects inequality. The blue area underneath the Lorenz curve is B, and the Gini coefficient can now be calculated as A/(A+B). Gini coefficients are often expressed as percentages.

Draw a Lorenz curve and explain its significance.

Lorenz curve: A Lorenz curve shows the degree of inequality that exists in the distributions of two variables, and is often used to illustrate the extent that income or wealth is distributed unequally in a particular society.

A Lorenz curve shows the % of income earned by a given % of the population.

A ‘perfect’ income distribution would be one where each % received the same % of income.

Perfect equality would be, for example, where 60% of the population gain 60% of national income. In the above Lorenz curve, 60% of the population gain only 20% of the income, hence the curve diverges from the line of perfect equality of income.

The further the Lorenz curve is from the 45-degree line, the less equal is the distribution of income.

The Lorenz Curve and Income Inequality

Quantifying Income inequality part 1

Quantifying Income inequality part 2

Analyze data on relative income shares of given percentages of the population, including deciles and quintiles.

It is possible to measure how equally or unequally a price system rations by looking at the distribution of income. The table below shows that during 2008, 20% of households with the lowest level of income in the United States (groups of people living together, usually families, or single people if they live alone) received only 3.4% of the total income that households earned. The top fifth of Households with the highest level of income earned 50% of the total income earned. The rest of the table can be interpreted in the same way.

The information in the table can be made into a Lorenz curve such as that shown below. The further the Lorenz curve lies below the line of equality, the more unequal is the distribution of income

How to calculate quintiles

Wealth Inequality in America

Income inequality Philosophy

Income inequality is good

Gap between China's rich and poor

Gini Index

Questions on Poverty, Gini Coefficient and Lorenz Curve

Task 1: (a) Use the following information to plot a Lorenz Curve

(b) What is the relationship between the Gini Coefficient and the Lorenz Curve?

Task 2: The following table gives the income distribution in Country A and Country B. Draw the Lorenz Curve for each. Which country has the larger Gini coefficient?

Task 3: Analyse the distribution of income, using the household incomes in the following table.

Table 1: Income of a sample of 10 households in PR China

    • Rank the families by income (lowest to highest)
    • Compute the percentage of total income going to the lowest 20% of the families, the second 20%, third 20%, fourth 20% and finally the richest 20%.
    • Draw a Lorenz Curve for the income distribution of these 10 families
    • Table 2 gives you the distribution of income in PR China in the year 2010 (last year of data available). How does the distribution of income compare to the sample of 10 households?

Statistics, damn statistics!

All economic statistics have problems, and the Lorenz curve and the numbers from which it is constructed are no exceptions. Problems come from two sources: do the numbers actually measure what they are supposed to measure, and are the numbers accurate?

Income distribution is intended to tell us about the rich and the poor, or about how much discrimination exists in a system of price rationing. In a system of price rationing, however, differences in the ability to use income wisely also determine how much discrimination there is. If those who receive the most income, for example, also tend to be the most capable at using that income, then the picture that the Lorenz curve shows will understate the actual amount of inequality.

If rationing is not done solely by price, but by other methods as well, then looking at income data may be meaningless. In the United States, most rationing is done with price, but not all. For example, the purpose of public housing and food stamps is to prevent rationing by price. Both of these items are ignored in the data in the table. Also, one should be cautious when comparing income distributions among countries because their rationing systems can be very different. For example, comparisons of income distribution between the United States and the Soviet Union were not meaningful--although economists sometimes made them--because the Soviet Union not only relied heavily on queuing, but those with special status, such as party members, had access to stores denied to the ordinary citizen.

Households differ in size and average age, but these differences are not reflected in the table above. Neither is the fact that the amount of time over which income is earned affects the shape of the Lorenz curve. Larger households tend to earn more than smaller households. People in their thirties tend to earn more than people in their twenties. Households with four or five members, with more than one person working, and whose working members are between 35 and 55 tend to earn more than other households.

In a paper published in the American Economic Review in September of 1975, Morton Paglin concluded that ignoring the influence of age on earnings overstates inequality by 50%. There is also variability from year to year in how much households earn. Some people appear poor because they had an unusually bad year, and others will seem rich because they had an unusually good year. The shorter the period over which income is measured, the more unequal the distribution appears. Thus, if income were measured over a decade, the distribution would be more equal than any of the yearly distributions.

The other source of problems is in making the initial measurements. The data shown in the table were obtained from questionnaires given a sample of 56,000 households. Not all of these households gave correct answers.

Despite the measuring problems, it is clear that a system of price rationing will distribute goods less equally than will alternative systems such as those using queuing or coupons. Many people consider this inequality a major shortcoming of a market economy, and most critics of market systems emphasize this characteristic. Defenders of market systems, on the other hand, tend to downplay rationing issues, and instead focus on the ability of a market economy to coordinate information and incentives. These are tasks that markets seem to perform very well in comparison to the ways other systems do them.

Poverty

Distinguish between absolute poverty and relative poverty.

There are two ways to define poverty:

Absolute poverty

Defining absolute poverty means trying to agree a general definition of poverty which is valid at all times and for all economies – this is difficult to do.

The simplest definition of being poor is ‘…being unable to subsist…that is, being unable to eat, drink, have shelter and clothing. A common monetary measure of absolute poverty is ‘..receiving less than $1 a day…’’. (In 2008, the World Bank revised this figure to $1.25 a day, and then again to $1.90 a day in 2015.)

It is also possible to establish an international poverty line, at, say at $700 per capita per year, and then compare countries, by estimating the purchasing power equivalent of that sum in terms of the countries own currency.

Relative poverty

It can be argued that poverty is best understood in a relative way – what is poor in New York is not the same as what is poor in Mumbai (where over 50% of the population live in slums.)

Many relative definitions of poverty conclude that it is the inability to reach a minimum accepted standard of living in a particular society.

Another approach is to look at deprivation, the poor being defined as those who are deprived from the benefits of a modern economy.

Definitions of relative poverty vary considerably, but the definition of the UK government is typical for developed countries – this states that the poor are those living on ‘..less than 60% of median income..’.

If we take the international poverty line as a guide, then, as a region, Asia has the highest numbers of its population who are poor.

However, as a region of the world, Sub-Saharan Africa has the highest level of poverty as a proportion of total population, at over 60%. The second poorest region is Latin America, with 35% of its population poor.

Source - http://www.economicsonline.co.uk/Global_economics/Poverty.html

Absolute and Relative Poverty

Explain possible causes of poverty, including low incomes, unemployment and lack of human capital.

Factors that cause poverty in developed countries

Some people imagine that in a rich region like the EU no one can be poor or if they are it must be the result of some personal failings or problems. However, this is not the case. The overall persistent high level of poverty in the EU suggest that poverty is primarily the consequence of the way society is organized and resources are allocated, whether these are financial or other resources such as access to housing, health and social services, education and other economic, social and cultural services. Indeed, the fact that there are very different levels of poverty in different Member States demonstrates clearly that different approaches to allocating resources and opportunities leads to different outcomes. The least unequal societies in Europe tend to have the lowest levels of poverty. This is primarily because these Governments chooses to give priority to ensuring adequate minimum income levels and ensuring good access to services, through the social protection system and through guaranteeing minimum wage levels. They are usually the most effective at redistributing wealth through the tax and other systems. This means that the decisions over how to eradicate poverty in the end are political choices about the kind of society we want.

Key factors

In terms of individuals, some key factors are seen as making a person more at risk of being in poverty such as:

  • unemployment or having a poor quality (i.e. low paid or precarious) job as this limits access to a decent income and cuts people off from social networks;
  • low levels of education and skills because this limits people's ability to access decent jobs to develop themselves and participate fully in society;
  • the size and type of family i.e. large families and lone parent families tend to be at greater risk of poverty because they have higher costs, lower incomes and more difficulty in gaining well paid employment;
  • gender - women are generally at higher risk of poverty than men as they are less likely to be in paid employment, tend to have lower pensions, are more involved in unpaid caring responsibilities and when they are in work, are frequently paid less ;
  • disability or ill-health because this limits ability to access employment and also leads to increased day to day costs;
  • being a member of minority ethnic groups such as the Roma and immigrants/undocumented migrants as they suffer particularly from discrimination and racism and thus have less chance to access employment, often are forced to live in worse physical environments and have poorer access to essential services;
  • living in a remote or very disadvantaged community where access to services is worse.

All these factors create additional barriers and difficulties, but should be seen within the overall structural context of how a particular country chooses to distribute wealth and tackle inequality.

Source - http://www.poverty.org.uk/summary/eapn.shtml

Factors that cause poverty in developing countries

1. Income inequality

Research shows that when a country grows economically, overall poverty reduces. If the national income is not equally distributed among all communities in the country, there is a risk that poorer communities will end up poorer, and individuals will feel it most.

2. Conflicts and Unrests

About 33% of communities in absolute poverty live in places of conflict. In the past, countries like Rwanda and Sri-Lanka have suffered poverty as a result of years of tribal and civil wars. In recent years, Afghanistan, Iraq and the like are all going through difficult times and poverty is rife in these areas. Unrests result in massive loss of human live, diseases, hunger and violence, destruction of property and infrastructure, economic investments and quality labour. It is also a put-off for foreign investments. Wealth can never be created in such an environment.

3. Location, adverse ecology and location

Location of countries, as well as communities within the country can make people poor. Geographic and ecological factors such as mountains, swamps, deserts and the like have also made life conditions unbearable in many places. This is why some rural areas are poorer than others, even in the same country. For example, poverty in the Andes, Peru is six times higher than communities in the Amazonian region.

In other instances, some communities are cut off from the main economic centers of the country. They find themselves located so far from roads, markets, health services, schools and economic facilities. This makes it just impossible for the locals to access support and assistance, and also makes it discouraging for economic investors to consider investing there. In Bangladesh for example, poverty is severe in areas of physical remoteness, as indicated by the fact that seven rural districts are home to half of the country’s severely stunted children.

4. Natural disasters

Droughts, floods, hurricanes and other unexpected natural events cause deaths, illness and loss of income. In Ethiopia alone, there were 15 droughts (and famines) between 1978 and 1998 that led to the displacement, injury, or death of more than 1 million people. In better connected communities, families are able to come out of poverty and get on with their lives, but other remote and less accessible communities suffer for longer periods.

5. Ill Health and Disability

Poverty can also get worse if communities are affected with diseases such as Malaria and HIV aids. Diseases cause many deaths and children are left with no parents or care givers. Household wealth can also drain quickly with disable members. In many communities, disabled members are looked down upon and not allowed to inherit assets. They are considered a stigma and excluded from public events and exposure. This mentality can adversely affect the well-being of families. For example, the incidence of poverty is 15-44% higher in households with a disabled head or adult.

6. Inheritance of Poverty

Families that have had a lifetime of poverty tend to pass on the situation to their children. They cannot afford education for their children and children grow with no skills. Children work on the same family farms, and marry into families with similar conditions as they turn adults. They in turn pass on the tradition to their children.

7. Education, Training and skills

People who are educated or had some training or skills are in a better position to apply ideas and knowledge into fixing basic problems and enhancing their livelihoods. They are able to plan, follow instructions and get reach out to access information, tools and support that can improve their livelihoods. In the absence of training, skills or education, people cannot help themselves. They cannot prevent diseases, and cannot apply new ways of doing things. The result is that their poverty situation is worse of and are even more vulnerable than before.

8. Gender discrimination

In many African communities, girls were not allowed to be in school. Families preferred to invest in boys’ education than in girls. Women were also not allowed to do major economic activity and had less ownership of lands and assets. This idea negatively impacts on the well-being of women, and the development of their children is also impacted negatively.

Source - http://www.eschooltoday.com/poverty-in-the-world/causes-of-poverty.html

Causes of poverty

Causes of poverty in America

Explain possible consequences of poverty, including low living standards, and lack of access to health care and education in developed countries

The effects of poverty are intricately and deeply connected. However, it is helpful to individually identify its numerous effects before observing them in relation to one another. This, in turn, will provide insight as to the causes of poverty well as how to alleviate poverty entirely. Here are just five effects of poverty:

1. Education

Only 14 percent of the variation in a child’s performance can be attributed to school quality, according to Donald Hirsch, advisor to the Joseph Rowntree Foundation. This means that a child’s background has a significant effect on their performance in school. Children who come from low-income families are far less likely to perform well in school. According to Department for Education statistics, by the end of primary school, pupils in need of free school meals are estimated to be almost three terms behind their more affluent peers.

2. Child Development

Children living in poverty are more likely to learn poor health behaviors and are more susceptible to mental illness as they grow older. Children living in constant poverty also show the worst cognitive development, compared to children from higher socio-economic backgrounds. Children who are poor are often unable to participate in social, leisure and celebratory activities, which can negatively impact their self-esteem and friendships. They may feel less able to take advantage of learning opportunities in school, which can eventually hurt their future employment prospects.

3. Crime

The Edinburgh Study of Youth Transitions and Crime found that poverty had a significant and direct effect on young people’s likelihood to engage in violence at age 15. Young people living in a family where the head of the household was unemployed were also more likely to participate in criminal behavior. Even poor individuals with “low risk” backgrounds were more likely to engage in violence. This means that for certain types of young people, living in a poor household increases their risk of engaging in violence beyond what one would expect.

4. Low Social Mobility

Children born into poverty are also more likely to grow up to be poor. For example, poor teenagers in Britain in the 1970s are twice as likely to be poor as adults, while poor teenagers in the 1980s are four times as likely to remain poor. When parents cannot find stable work, they are unable to provide their children with necessary attention and resources. This ultimately makes it more difficult for them to build a better life for their children in the future.

5. Extra Social Spending

When adults are unable to meet their full potential in society, they contribute less productively to the economy. They often receive payment benefits and reduced tax revenues, which necessitates extra social spending. The Joseph Rowntree Foundation estimates that child poverty costs the United Kingdom at least £25 billion a year. This includes £12 billion a year on public spending on services that alleviate the immediate effects of poverty. The remaining £13 billion accounts for the annual costs of below average employment rates.

The key to alleviating poverty is to coordinate humanitarian efforts between these many factors. Once we understand the effects of poverty and their many dimensions, we can take the necessary steps to eradicate the issue altogether.

– Liliana Rehorn

Source - https://borgenproject.org/5-effects-poverty/

Few winners in South Africa

The role of taxation in promoting equity

Distinguish between direct and indirect taxes, providing examples of each, and explain that direct taxes may be used as a mechanism to redistribute income.

Direct Taxation

When a wage earner receives his/her wages, income tax has for the most part already been deducted. Other taxes which are levied directly on individual incomes are taxes on profits, interest received, capital gains taxes (on income earned by selling property or shares) and dividends from the ownership of shares. Other economic agents, e.g. firms, pay corporate taxes (often called profit taxes), and labour taxes. In each of these cases, the tax is clearly distinguishable and goes directly from the taxpayer to the tax office; these are direct taxes.

Direct taxes on income are associated with two main economic effects.

1) The first is the redistribution effect, whereby income tax is collected and then redistributed to other (less fortunate) members of society. Note that this is not only in the form of money (see ‘transfer payments’ below) but also in the form of health care, education and road networks (‘benefits in kind’ below).

2) The second effect is the possibility of a disincentives effect; when taxes on income increase at higher income levels, workers might not view additional working hours as worthwhile. It is also possible that an unemployed person gets a job and incurs a net loss of disposable income when income tax is paid at the same time as various social benefits disappear – this is a form of poverty trap for low income households. In addition, there is the possibility of a parallel labour market when increasing tax levels create an incentive for workers to avoid taxes by not reporting income to the tax office.

Indirect Taxation

A good deal of government tax revenue is comprised of taxes on expenditure such as value added taxes (VAT), specific taxes commonly levied on petrol and alcohol (excise duties) and import taxes (tariffs). All of these are indirect taxes, since economic exchanges such as consumption/expenditure rather than individuals are taxed. The tax paid is baked into the exchange and goes – indirectly – to government via the firms selling the goods.

Indirect taxes affect supply which implies that market equilibrium is negatively affected; the supply curve for the good shifts left. While the case is often that this causes a misallocation of resources (and deadweight loss), we have also seen that in fact taxes might serve to decrease negative externalities and therefore instead increase allocative efficiency. An issue worthy of notice here is whether a tax on a good having negative externalities should be designated to cover only its own costs or not. For example, many countries have road taxes which contribute to government tax receipts far in excess of what is subsequently paid for building and renovating roads. A strong case can be made by car owners that they are paying more than their fair share of taxes, since any surplus receipts will benefit those who do not own cars. The counterargument is that road usage is strongly associated with negative externalities such as pollution and noise, so the additional tax is an adequate disincentive for road use.

Task 6: Explain how individuals’ behaviour is affected by the following features of the US taxation code (many of the features are also part of the HK tax code)

a) Contributions to charity are tax deductible

b) Sales of beer are taxed

c) Interest that a homeowner pays on a mortgage is tax deductible

d) Realized capital gains are taxed but accrued gains are not (when someone owns a share/stock/equity that rises in value, she has an accrued capital gain. If she sells the share/stock/equity, she has a realized gain

Distinguish between progressive, regressive and proportional taxation, providing examples of each.

Progressive Taxation system

Direct taxation has one clear advantage over indirect taxes, namely that a direct tax can be adjusted to conform to societal views on equity. Income tax rates can be adjusted to each person’s ability to pay, i.e. adjusted to income. A progressive tax on income means that higher income will result in a higher percentage of tax paid, i.e. an increasing proportion of income goes to tax. Most countries will have a systematic increase in the proportion (= percentage) of income tax paid as income rises, since this is virtually the only way in which income can be redistributed – by ‘taking from the rich and giving to the poor’. Commonly in income tax systems, there is a minimum income level where no tax is paid, whereupon the marginal tax – the tax paid on the last money earned – increases.

For example, say that income tax on the first €2,000 is zero but 15% on any income above this. Earning €3,000 would mean that income tax would be paid only on the additional €1,000 – the amount exceeding the threshold of €2,000. This is the marginal tax rate. Tax at an income of €3,000 would be €1,000  _0.15 = €150. (However – take heed! – the average tax on income is of course total tax paid over total income; €150 / €3,000 = 5%.)

The progressive taxation element in this method of income taxation is that higher income brackets will mean higher percentage tax paid. Continuing with the example, say that the tax rate progressively increases to 20% for income above €5,000 but below €10,000, and that a person’s income increases from €5,000 to €7,000. The marginal tax on the €2,000 above the €5,000 tax bracket is €400 while the average tax paid will be €3,000 x 0.15 + €2,000 x 0.2 = €850. The tax rate then increases at every higher income bracket. This is illustrated in the upward sloping – progressive – curve where the marginal tax rate is of course the slope of the curve.

Proportional Tax

A proportional tax is exactly what it sounds like; a percentage of income paid in tax. Since the percentage is unchanged at higher income levels, there is no marginal tax effect and any rise in income will add to total tax payment at a constant rate, so average tax rate is unchanged. In other words, the proportional tax curve will have a constant slope. Capital gains, corporate profits and dividends are types of income which are frequently taxed on a proportional basis.

Regressive Taxation

Just as indirect taxes can be ‘flat rate’ – such as unit taxes on wine – direct taxation can consist of a fixed sum which does not change as income rises, which means that average taxes paid fall as income rises. A regressive tax means that the average proportion of tax paid on income or profit falls as income/profit increases. For example, a yearly business registration tax of £1,000 for a small corner shop with £20,000 in profit means 5% average tax. For Imperial Tobacco Group PLC, the £423 million in profit in 2012 would mean that the registration tax is on average 0,00023%. Since the average tax payment as a proportion of income is falling, the regressive tax curve will become successively shallower.

Another regressive effect of taxation is that lower income groups are often hit harder by indirect taxes than higher income groups. Alcohol, tobacco and petrol are all major contributors to total government tax revenues and contain a large element of flat-rate tax (excise duty). The regressive element herein is when low income earners pay the same tax as high income earners; the former are spending a greater proportion of income on the goods than the latter. In fact, value added taxes are arguably regressive since a 10% sales tax on a £100 purchase constitutes a far larger part of income for a person earning £12,000 than for someone earning £120,000. One could say that this lowers the effectiveness of any intended redistribution effects of the tax.

Visual depiction of the three systems of taxation

Source - http://goodbadecon.com/uploads/3/1/1/6/3116093/ch_55_-_equity_and_distr_of_income_-_2.3.pdf

Task 7: Ms. Jones has a taxable income of US$30000, and she must pay tax of US$3000. Mr. Smith has a taxable income of US$60000. How much tax must Mr. Smith pay for the tax system to be:

(a) Progressive

(b) Regressive

(c) Proportional

What do you think is the relationship between the average rate of tax (ART) and marginal rate of tax (MRT) under the three types of taxation systems?

Examples of Flat tax rates on income tax

Advantages & disadvantages of a flat tax

What is the case for a flat tax?

Direct and indirect taxes

The Progressive Income tax

Calculate the marginal rate of tax and the average rate of tax from a set of data (HL only)

Average rate of Tax (ART)

The average tax rate is the tax rate you pay when you add all sources of taxable income and divide that number into the amount of taxes you owe. In other words, you can calculate your average tax rate by dividing your total tax obligation by your total taxable income.

Formula: Tax payable/Taxable income x 100

For example, if you earn $50,000 in salary for one year, and you must pay $10,000 in taxes, then the applicable income tax rate/average tax rate is 20% i.e. which is 20% of the value of your annual income.

Source - http://study.com/academy/lesson/average-tax-rate-definition-formula-quiz.html

Marginal rate of Tax (MRT)

Your marginal tax rate is the extra taxes you pay on each additional dollar of income you make. The marginal rate is calculated by taking the change in total tax paid divided by the change in income, times 100; (ΔT/Δy) x 100.

For example, imagine that you are a couple whose taxable income equals $50,000. You wish to calculate the marginal tax rate on a new venture that will earn you $35,000. The tax authorities will charge you 15 percent on the first $18,000 of that $35,000 and will charge you 25 percent on the remaining $17,000.

Step 1: Multiply each portion of the new income by its tax rate: 0.15 × $18,000 = $2,700; 0.25 × 17,000 = $4,250.

Step 2: Add these results together: $2,700 + $4,250 = $6,950.

Step 3: Divide this new sum by the income whose rate you're calculating: $6,950 ÷ $35,000 = 0.198571429.

Step 4: Multiply this answer by 100: 0.198571429 × 100 = 19.8571429.

Step 5: Round this result to a level that suits your needs. 19.8571429 is approximately 19.86, so this is the marginal tax rate on the additional income.

Source - http://thefinancebase.com/calculate-marginal-tax-rate-economics-4244.html

Different tax systems and effects on income distribution Part 1

Different tax systems and effects on income distribution Part 2

Task 8: Calculating ART & MRT

(a) Progressive Taxation

A tax is progressive when it takes a greater percentage of income or wealth from the high income or wealthier groups than it does from the low income, poorer groups in society. E.g. Portugal’s system of Income Tax.

Example

Tax is levied as follows:

● First €4000 of taxable income is taxed at 25%

● Next €12000 of taxable income is taxed at 50%

● Any income above that is taxed at 80%

(b) Proportional Taxation

A tax is proportional when all taxpayers pay the same percentage of their income or wealth. E.g. Corporation Tax – tax on corporate profits.

Example

Profits are taxed at 40%

(c) Regressive taxation

Taxes are regressive when they take a greater percentage of income or wealth from the poor/low-income sectors of society. E.g. taxes such as excise duty on tobacco, beer and petrol act regressively since the amount of tax included in the prices of these goods represents a greater % of the incomes of poorer groups.

Example

Tax is levied as follows:

● First €4000 of taxable income is taxed at 60%

● Next €4000 of taxable income is taxed at 30%

● Next €12000 of taxable income is taxed at 20%

● Any income above that is taxed at 10%

Task 9: Given the data in the table below, draw the Lorenz curve before and after the proposed tax. Is this tax progressive or regressive?

Task 10: The average tax rate is defined as total taxes paid divided by income. The marginal tax rate is defined as the extra taxes paid on additional income divided by the increase in income.

a. Describe the relationship between average tax rates and the marginal tax rates for each of the three taxation systems.

b. In general, which rate is relevant for someone deciding whether to accept a job that pays slightly more than her current job?

Task 11: Complete the following table, which describes the sales tax paid by individuals at various income levels. Indicate whether the tax is progressive, proportional or regressive.

Task 12: Suppose that the HK government raises its sales tax from 5% to 6%. The finance minister forecasts a 20% increase in sales tax revenue. Is this plausible? Explain.

Take the pre-tax price of the good as being HK$100 and the number of units sold at the original sales revenue (when 5% tax is applied) as being 10,000.

Task 13: The Tax Reform Act of 1986 (US) eliminated the deductibility of interest payments on consumer debt (mostly credit cards and automobile loans) but maintained the deductibility of interest payments on mortgages and home equity loans. What do you think happened to the relative amounts of borrowing through consumer debt and home equity debt?

Task 14: What is the efficiency justification for taxing consumption rather than income? If HK were to adopt a consumption tax, like some Caribbean countries, do you think it would make the HK Tax System more or less progressive? Explain.

Task 15: If a salesperson takes a client to lunch, part of the lunch is a deductible business expense for his company. Some members of the US Congress have argued that this feature of the tax code benefits relatively wealthy businesspeople and should be eliminated. Yet their arguments have been met with greater opposition from eating and drinking establishments than from companies themselves. Explain.

Task 16: Tax Systems and Income Distribution

Introduction: The government of Country X currently collects taxes on individuals’ income at rates represented in the 2014 column in the following table. The government is considering the implementation of an expansionary fiscal policy in 2015 involving an across the board reduction in tax rates as represented in the 2015 column. Study the table then answer the questions that follow:

I. Calculate the amount of tax paid in 2014 by an individual in country X earning

a. $32,000

b. $60,000

II. Calculate the amount of tax paid in 2015 by the same individuals (assuming their incomes remained the same as in 2014).

c. $32,000

d. $60,000

III. Calculate the average tax rates in 2015 faced by the individual earning

e. $32,000

f. $60,000

IV. Explain why the average tax rate differs from each individual’s marginal tax rate.

V. How will a decrease in the income tax rate affect the value of the spending multiplier in Country X?

VI. The Lorenz Curve below represents the distribution of family income in Country X.

a. Add labels and values to the axes.

b. Assume there is no change in government spending in Country X. Draw a new Lorenz curve showing how the change in marginal tax rates will affect income distribution in 2015. Label it “2015a”

c. Explain how Country X’s Gini coefficient is derived and how the change in the marginal tax rates will affect the Gini coefficient.

I. An alternative plan for fiscal stimulus being discussed by the government of Country X involves reducing the value added tax (VAT), an indirect tax on consumption, from 15% to 8%.

a. Explain how a reduction in the VAT will affect aggregate demand in Country X.

b. On the Lorenz Curve diagram above, show the effect a reduction in the VAT will have on the level of income distribution in Country X. Label the new Lorenz Curve “2015b”

c. Explain how a reduction in the VAT affects income distribution.

II. Supporters of the proposed income tax rate reduction argue that it will increase productivity and efficiency in the economy. Why might this argument be justified?

III. Opponents of the proposed income tax rate reduction argue that it will decrease equity in Country X. Why might this argument be justified?

IV. Explain how a fiscal stimulus that combines the proposed income tax cuts and an simultaneously increases the provision of public goods and transfer payments could address the concerns of the opponents to the income tax cut. Why is such a compromise harmful to the government’s budget balance?

Explain the term transfer payments, and provide examples, including old age pensions, unemployment benefits and child allowances

Societies often find it necessary and prudent to provide benefits for certain groups of citizens. Social (welfare) benefit systems which redistribute income via cash transfer payments exist in most countries in some form. Students will receive grants and soft loans; retired people receive pensions and additional health care monies; low income households and single parents (far too often one and the same) receive supplemental housing allowance and welfare payments; and unemployed people receive unemployment benefits and perhaps travel contributions for job seeking.

Definition: “transfer payments”

Any government monies granted to households – without some form of corresponding output – is a transfer payment. Unemployment benefits, housing allowances for low income families and social benefits are examples of transfer payments.

Explain that governments undertake expenditures to provide directly, or to subsidize, a variety of socially desirable goods and services (including health care services, education, and infrastructure that includes sanitation and clean water supplies), thereby making them available to those on low incomes.

The other main form of societal redistribution is services in kind; merit goods such as health care and education. Since these goods would be both underprovided and thus under-consumed on a free market, it would be the poorer groups who would suffer the most. By using government (tax) monies to provide these goods on a general basis of not-for-profit, total economic welfare is increased.

Definition: “services in kind”

Under-provided and under-consumed goods such as public transport, education and health care are services often provided directly or indirectly (subsidies) by governments. These services in kind have highly positive regressive effects as they benefit poorer households proportionally more than wealthier

Source - http://goodbadecon.com/uploads/3/1/1/6/3116093/ch_55_-_equity_and_distr_of_income_-_2.3.pdf

Transfer payments

Relationship between equity and efficiency

Evaluate government policies to promote equity (taxation, government expenditure and transfer payments) in terms of their potential positive or negative effects on efficiency in the allocation of resources.

All taxes will in some way lead to market distortions, since they lead to a decrease in supply and concomitant decrease in quantity demanded. Taxes on labour lead to higher costs for firms and an increase in unemployment; indirect taxes lead to less goods being consumed; corporate taxes lead to fewer new firms and less investment; and capital gains tax reduces incentives and lowers economic activity. However, the economic argument in favour of enduring these distortions is that the allocative losses can be made up for by the overall redistribution gains to society in terms of public and merit goods. Governments use tax receipts to provide goods which are beneficial to all of society. For example, the efficiency loss in firms due to labour taxes are offset by productivity gains arising from a well-educated work force, and the relatively small decrease in consumption arising due to high marginal taxes on the richest 1% can be offset by welfare gains when the taxes are redistributed to poorer groups.

It gets trickier when governments have to decide which tax creates the ‘fairest’ outcome. Indirect taxes have the advantage of being simple and easy to collect, but have the disadvantage of levying a heavier burden on the poor than the rich. For example, a unit tax of €2 per litre of alcoholic beverage will have a far greater real income effect on Otto Normalverbraucher14 purchasing a €3 six-pack of beer than it will have on Countess Antoinette du la Monet15 buying a €150 bottle of 1966 Chateau Neuf du Pape. In effect, a flat-rate tax expenditure tax will have strong regressive tax effects on poorer groups.

As for income taxes, where is it written that higher income must lead to higher proportion of tax – when in fact a proportional tax already means that higher income leads to more tax payments?! The argument for progressive income taxes (‘higher income = higher percentage tax’) is highly normative, in that there is an evening-out effect of incomes which is ‘fair’ to society in general. Increased income equality also has economic benefits, such as lower crime rates and inner city regeneration which, of course, benefits everyone. Quite naturally, the well-off point out that between one third and half of all income tax receipts in developed countries come from the top 5% income earners – the implication being that this is “more than their fair share”. Another common argument put forward by the affluent is that progressive taxes are a major disincentive for people to push themselves, being in fact a ‘punitive tax’ on achievement, hard work and entrepreneurial spirit.

Redistributing income has a double-edged price tag of administrative costs to government and allocative losses to society. Redistribution has been likened to attempting to transfer water from one bucket to another.16 A portion of the water – income – will invariably be lost in the process, i.e. there will be costs associated with administration and economic efficiency. The taxes on economic endeavours such as labour and investment also render opportunity costs in the form of forgone…labour and investment. This argument thus puts forward that attempting to improve social welfare by increasing equity will render a social cost in terms of greater inefficiency in the use of resources which leads to a loss of income.

The basic question here is whether the costs to society of trying to increase equity are counterproductive in terms of economic growth. The trade-off, according to this line of reasoning, is between growth in total income and growth in income equality. In the final analysis, a good many studies show that there is indeed a trade-off – increased income inequality is ‘pro-growth’. However, a good many studies show the reverse, i.e. that greater inequality leads to lower growth! And for my final trick; a recent study by the OECD showed “…no evidence that the level of income inequality affects GDP one way or another.”

Source - http://goodbadecon.com/uploads/3/1/1/6/3116093/ch_55_-_equity_and_distr_of_income_-_2.3.pdf

What is the government's role in income inequality?

American Dream Myth: Stiglitz on income inequality

Brazil looks to tackle income inequality

Bernie Sanders on income inequality

South Africa: Using Fiscal Policy to tackle economic inequality

Do Federal Taxes reduce income inequality?

Questions on evaluation of government policies to promote equity

Task 17: If the incidence of poverty decreases during periods when the economy is growing and increases during periods when the economy is in recession, what government policies might be used to reduce poverty most effectively?

Task 18: Some economists argue that we should use more progressive taxes, while others claim that we should adopt a flat tax. List some reasons for and against using progressive taxes.

Task 19: Suppose the government is trying to decide between putting a sales tax on luxuries, which usually have very high demand elasticities, or on petrol. Answer the following with diagrams:

a) Which tax will have a larger effect on the market price?

b) Which tax will cause the quantity traded in the market to decline more?

Files to download

2.3 macroeconomic objectives - Inequality.pptx
Equity & Efficiency.ppt