Superannuation & Tax

This page presents comprehensive tax reform proposals, covering individual income tax, superannuation and consumption taxes (merged as an integrated system), welfare (especially through a Universal Basic Income) and company tax (in particular using a "cash-flow" tax).  The objectives are to substantially improve efficiency (both in terms of tax incentives and administration), as well as fairness (through a more progressive system that taxes those who can most afford it) and flexibility to individual needs (particularly in the case of superannuation tax & regulations).  A broader discussion of inequality and economic management is at this page.

The reform proposals here are divided into the following sections:

(A) Reform of superannuation tax & regulations;
NB. I submitted this pdf version of section A (as at 13 Feb. 2020) to the Australian Treasury 2019-20 Retirement Income Review.

(B) Welfare reforms to support improved equality along with flexible & productive employment
        especially through a Universal Basic Income (UBI), which would be especially helpful for managing economic disruptions like those caused by Covid-19;

(C) Rationalising tax administration by integrating income tax and sales tax (GST/VAT) with the proposed superannuation tax changes – delivering a more efficient and fairer, progressive system;

(D) Reforming company tax through the introduction of a universal "business cash-flow tax";

(E) Finalising a comprehensive tax & welfare reform strategy.

(A) Reform of Australian superannuation taxation and regulation

The current superannuation system is inflexible and complex, which explains why despite its very expensive & unfair tax concessions, the average Australian has as much in savings outside super as they do inside it.  It doesn't meet the needs of a modern, flexible and ageing population. It needs fundamental reform.

The attached paper, "supertaxreform-final updated2012", presents a vision for simple, flexible, customer-focussed superannuation (to support flexible careers and retirement) that is fair and sustainable in its tax treatment.  The paper has evolved over the years through various submissions (initially to ASFA's 2005 competition and to the 2006-07 Budget, which Costello & Dutton failed to grasp).  Here's a news article about my long-standing campaign on the issue.

The inevitable need for such tax reforms due to an ageing population is put forward in my one-page paper, "AgeingSuperTaxReformJan2017" (also published here).

The following are the key points of my proposed superannuation reforms:


An initially voluntary new "Flexi-Super" scheme (voluntary for at least older workers, over, say 45), with the following features:

a) No tax on contributions (i.e. made from pre-tax income, or with tax credits granted for post-tax income contributions).

b) A low tax on earnings (say 15%) for funds below a defined maximum balance that provides for "comfortable" retirement.

(This tax would apply at all ages, including in “retirement”, but may be offset by tax credits paid by companies on their distributions to shareholders.
Higher tax rates may apply to earnings on funds above the maximum balance, but these may generate tax offsets for subsequent withdrawal tax.)

c) Withdrawals (for spending on consumption) taxed at progressive rates, similar to income tax (and replacing income tax as in part C below).

d) Funds could be withdrawn at any age (e.g. for a mid-career break or unemployment period), as long as the balance exceeds a regulated minimum amount that would rise with age (the minimum, specified by age, would be based on the savings required to retire with a basic 'minimum' standard of living, i.e. less than "comfortable")
this flexibility addresses probably the biggest barrier to voluntary contributions under the current superannuation regime.

e) 10% of wages must only be contributed if the fund balance is below the regulated minimum (for the person's age) noting the arguments for more than 10% (made by the self-interested super industry) are not strong.


Besides being simple, having all tax benefits on earnings (a low tax rate) automatically rewards people for saving longer and thus avoids the need for complex regulations limiting annual contributions and withdrawals.  And with progressive tax rates applied to withdrawals, the more that's withdrawn in any single year, the higher the % rate of tax that will apply so there's an incentive to withdraw funds gradually.

The proposed tax treatment would also benefit people taking a voluntary or forced career break, because the marginal tax on withdrawal could be at a lower rate than during prior high-income periods of their career.  For example, the tax paid by someone earning $100k in year 1 who saves $50k of this in superannuation to withdraw in year 2 when out of work, would be the same as someone who worked two years at $50k p.a., unlike the current income tax system, which taxes you at a higher % rate for earning a given amount if it is concentrated into one year rather than two, thus actively discouraging employment contracts that respond faster (more efficiently) to varying demand.  Hence these proposals could encourage greater job mobility with more frequent vacancies and more opportunities for those looking for work thus potentially reducing unemployment.

There may also be other 'externality' (society-wide) benefits arising from people taking more career breaks to focus on their families or other aspects of life.


Pragmatic implementation could be assisted by:

(B) Welfare reform

These superannuation reforms could also enable comprehensive rationalisation & reform of the broader tax system (including income tax and GST, as discussed in part C below) as well as facilitate the following potential welfare-system reforms to support flexible employment markets, through integration of the aged pension with superannuation and a Universal Basic-Income:

Allowing the option to invest in home ownership rather than the stock market can be justified as a matter of principle, but to moderate the risk that an excessive use of super funds for home ownership could inflate property prices (thereby reducing the net benefit of these individuals' choice to invest in their own home), the funds withdrawn escalated in line with a property price index should be included in the measure of total assets that determines eligibility for government co-contributions (that fund the equivalent of the aged pension).  Refinancing an owned home in retirement to fund enhanced living expenses could also then be automatically and consistently encouraged.

In addition, excessive investor demand for housing could of course be moderated by Reserve Bank monetary policy and/or by APRA through lending controls as suggested here.

Universal Basic Income (UBI)

Wealth inequality is more pronounced than income inequality
(refer final sentence of Welfare Reform point 1 above)

In 2015–16, ABS data reveals that the mean Australian disposable equivalised-household income (after tax & Medicare levies), at $1009 per week, was 18% higher than the median (which 50% of households have less than), but the large wealth accumulated by a small fraction of households (the top 1% own as much as the bottom 70%) made the mean household wealth 76% higher than the median and the wealthiest 20% of Australian households owned 63% of total household wealth, which was 80 times more than the less-than-1% owned by the lowest 20% of households.  By 2018, the Credit-Suisse Global Wealth report indicated the ratio of mean to median Australian wealth had risen to over 2x, while in the UK & USA it was nearly 3x & more than 6x respectively.

Greater inequity in wealth over the 15 years since the 2008 "Global Financial Crisis" has been caused by low wages growth and high asset price growth (driven by low interest rates), plus relatively low tax on investment earnings (including super), resulting in 93% of the gains from economic growth going to the top 10% of income earners (pre tax), even without much change in income equality.

(C) Integrating income tax and a progressive sales tax with superannuation

The reforms proposed above for superannuation tax would largely replace income tax and also constitute a progressive consumption or sales tax (GST or VAT), because tax would only apply to people's income when they withdrew funds to spend it.  It would be equivalent to (but administratively far more efficient than) applying a GST to every transaction with an increased % rate for wealthier people that spend more.  Hence there would then be no need for "luxury goods" taxes (nor administratively costly exemptions) and even the GST itself would become administratively redundant and could be abolished, at least for domestic production (see below for imports).  Philosophically it makes sense to tax consumption rather than income, because it is consumption choices that determine how society's limited human and natural resources are utilised.  Tax (spending) allowances could be rolled over into future years so that tax liabilities for major one-off purchases like homes & cars are assessed and paid on the basis of average lifetime consumption (and so that tax is not distorted by financing mechanisms).

Further major economic efficiencies would come from consolidation of banking & super industries as people choose to bank almost all their savings in their super account because why would you put money in the bank when you can leave it in super with a lower tax on earnings and still access most of it?  Nevertheless, people could still choose to periodically transfer their estimated annual spending needs to a separate spending account, which would incur withdrawal/consumption tax when transferred, on the assumption that it will be spent in that financial year.  The funds in this post-tax spending account could then be readily compared like-for-like with retail prices (that would incur no further tax).  An automatic year-end assessment would then adjust the annual tax liability for any residual unspent funds left in the spending account (as if it had not been transferred from their super savings account).  These arrangements could also help to reduce the psychological impact of taxation, since it would mostly be incurred automatically, similarly to current PAYGO systems.  Another implementation option, with potential enforcement benefits, would be to initially apply the tax at the maximum rate to all company sales, then make adjustments for individuals (according to their annual spending) once they've provided satisfactory tax returns.

Tax avoidance could be minimised as current income tax administered by employers would be redundant and a fixed top tax rate (with no deductions) could be applied to all funds or income not held in, or transferred out of accredited superannuation savings accounts (e.g. to overseas tax havens).  Current opportunities for income tax deductions should be much reduced anyway, as they are in most other countries.  Parents could effectively get an extra allowance for dependent children by donating from their pre-tax income (in their super fund) to their children's superannuation accounts, which they could then use to meet living expenses (thus effectively getting an extra tax-free spending allowance).  But aside from this, tax & welfare should not depend on whether an adult is sharing accommodation with another adult whether they be friend, partner or otherwise as it makes no sense for society to penalise people for sharing companionship, love and assets, and the state has no business prying into such things as it is increasingly doing (plus de facto laws deny people the right to choose whether or not to make a marriage commitment, and should be repealed now gay people have been granted marriage equality).

For domestic investors & corporations, a superannuation earnings tax of 15% would be equivalent to a 15% corporations tax but applied one step beyond the corporation (on dividends paid to individual investors, rather than on the corporation's aggregate profit).  Hence it would seem to make sense to set Australian corporation tax at the same consistent level of 15% (which would capture retained profits), with existing dividend-imputation rules enabling individual Australian investors to offset this corporations tax paid against the 15% tax payable on their superannuation fund earnings (at least for funds below the regulated "maximum" super fund balance providing for concessionary tax).  However, this proposition needs to be considered within the context of the following proposed structural changes to company tax.

(D) A business "cash-flow tax"

A company 'cash flow tax', as suggested in the Henry Tax Review and further developed by Garnaut et al., has a lot of attractions in terms of reduced administration cost & multi-national tax avoidance, as well as – most importantly – greater economic efficiency, because in contrast to existing taxes it presents literally no disincentive for investments, even if levied at 30% or more for returns on investment above the benchmark rate (so-called "super-profits", which don't just occur in mining industries).  It should also remove distortions to business financing currently caused by allowing tax deductions for interest but not dividends (the equivalent of interest for equity lenders), which could make the problem of "negative gearing" redundant.

Conceptually a business cash-flow tax has similarities to the GST and the above superannuation tax proposals, and many of its perceived problems particularly from not directly taxing profits retained for reinvestment could possibly be addressed if it were applied in combination with the above proposals for taxing corporation profits & superannuation investment earnings.  Together they would basically create a progressive company tax, which is not something you can otherwise do like with personal income tax (because big companies with big profits would simply break up into smaller companies so they each incur a smaller tax rate).

A cash-flow tax offers a number of other potential advantages:

The question then arises as to how to treat imports.  If we assume imports are made in a country with similar taxes and regulatory standards (e.g. for environmental protection), and therefore are competing on equal terms, then the best economic outcome may be achieved from a level-playing field for competition between local production and imports with no import taxes (despite the disadvantage of imports providing less tax revenue to the Australian Government, because it can't tax foreign companies' profits).  However, if we take the view that all consumption should be taxed equally to pay for the public services Australia wants, then this suggests we would like to receive the same tax revenue from imports as from local production.  Given foreign countries may not actually have similar taxes and regulatory standards, a pragmatic position might be to apply a sales tax of around 10% on imports only, unless agreed otherwise through international trade negotiations.  A 10% import sales tax would be unchanged from the current GST (whilst the GST would be subsumed into superannuation withdrawal tax for domestic goods) and, depending on profit margins & other factors of production, may raise similar revenue to that from company taxes applied to local production.

(E) Finalising a comprehensive tax & welfare reform strategy

The discussion above provides a new more efficient and fair structural framework for taxation, which would involve the drastic rationalisation (abolition) of many existing taxes, with one integrated tax on personal income/savings/spending replacing existing separate taxes on superannuation savings, consumption (GST) and income (including State payroll taxes, which are just another form of income tax).

Implementation would need to be staged over many years (to ease the pain of any transition for certain groups), and obviously requires further detailed analysis and refinement, especially to ensure enough revenue is raised for decent public services.  Particular issues to consider include:

So there we have it!  It all sounds too easy doesn't it?  But while resolving details may be complex, from a strategic perspective I don't think these are especially tricky problems they just need to be tackled by people who aren't wedded to the status quo, because the aim is not to produce a "perfect" system (which isn't possible); it's to clean up what's widely regarded as an inefficient mess.

Economists know that taxation affects economic trading activities, which involve the interaction of producers/employees, investors and consumers, so applying multiple taxes to different parties in this trade (e.g. income tax and profit tax and GST) generally just adds administration costs compared to one simple tax on the trade (ultimately money just facilitates bartering, so you never really get paid for your labour until you cash-in your IOU in return for bread).

But the world's taxation systems have grown over many, many years into the mess they are through a combination of short-term, timid political incrementalism & compromise, plus equally cautious advice from accountants (who make money from having complex tax & accounting systems) along with lobbying from self-interested business leaders seeking loopholes under cover of proclaimed but generally non-existent economic expertise (there's a big difference between knowing how to run a business and understanding the economy).