Between free trade and over-protection

In economic policymaking, every policy hurts some groups and helps others. All advice is automatically biased in favor of some group or the other. Economic theories cannot be understood without understanding the historical context in which they were formulated, and the group interests which they served. The most striking example of this is the theory of free trade. This theory emerged in England, after England had acquired a fifty year lead over other European countries via the industrial revolution. Thus England was a small country which had acquired capabilities of manufacturing vast amounts of surplus. What was to be done with this surplus? This was the historical context for the famous Say’s Law which says that supply creates its own demand. Treating theories as universal laws valid everywhere creates enormous barriers to understanding. Students struggle to grasp difficult mathematical formulae without any clue as to the meaning or relevance of the formula.

Say’s law suggested that increased domestic incomes created by the production of surplus would increase the domestic demand for the excess production. The doctrine of free trade was designed to lower ideological barriers and thus create foreign demand for the surplus production of England. According to this doctrine, free trade is always helpful to both traders. This is based on a very simple idea. If both parties agree to the trade then both must benefit, otherwise they would not agree. Even for individuals, we can easily visualize situations where this is not true. Advertisers can make products appear attractive and seduce people into buying unnecessary products at outrageous prices. At the level of nations, this principle is extremely misleading. European nations were deceived by the free trade theories into allowing English products to penetrate their markets. This adversely affected local producers and led to a recession in the European economies. At this point the great German economist Friedrich List understood the game and rose to the defense of Germany. He created the “infant industry” argument, saying that German industry could never develop in free competition with the English who were so far ahead. They must be protected and nurtured until they could stand on their feet. He argued that the free trade theories work well if the two parties are equals, but not in situations where one has a dominant advantage over the other. His theories were applied with great success. Protection led to the development of German Industry, until they were able to compete on equal terms with the English. At this point, it became possible and advantageous to remove the trade barriers.

In general, all cases of successful industrialization in the twentieth century have been achieved by protection, together with government leadership and support. Nonetheless, protection is not always beneficial. In the USA, Japanese competition was causing immense damage to the US auto industry, who asked for protection. While this was against the free trade ideology of the USA, the automakers were sufficiently influential and succeed in imposing VER – Voluntary Export Restrictions on Japan. The automobile industry promptly forgot their promises to improve efficiency, and instead made use of the respite from competition to jack up prices and make huge profits from the USA Consumers. At the same time, the Japanese cleverly moved up the value chain, shifting exports to high end luxury cars so that they would make more profits on the same volume of trade limits under the quota. Consumer prices for cars almost doubled within two years. This a common pattern seen in protected industries. Instead using the protection as a breathing space to prepare for the challenge of competition, to acquire strength and grow, protected industries grow fat, lazy and inefficient.

Simple minded arguments for protection and for free trade are both wrong. Development requires intelligent planning, not adherence to platitudes and ideological principles. The goal of overriding importance is the development of local capabilities. It is a general principle that development occurs in response to the right level of challenge. The level of challenge should be just enough to stimulate growth, but not so much as to cause collapse. The challenge should also be increased dynamically in response to the growth of capabilities.

The East Asian countries were well aware of the dilemmas of protection and used a very clever strategy to steer a middle course, avoiding both extremes. They provided a clear time-table along the following lines, adjusted according to the particular circumstances of the industry. The first year could be one of full protection, with a barrier on imports. This was the preparation year. The second year, export oriented industries would have to export 10% of their products to ensure that they were able to compete in the foreign market. In addition, the tariff barriers against foreigners would also be reduced, on a schedule designed to increase the level of challenge facing the industry. Faced with this clear cut schedule to achieve competitiveness, Industries worked to improve efficiency. It was a matter of survival. They learned how to manufacture for exports, and how to cut costs, increase efficiency and create quality. In all this process, they also did receive the help of the government. The successful transition from agrarian to industrial economy bears witness to the success of their strategy.

Posts on Diverse Topics:My author page on LinkedIn. Other works: Index . More material on Unlearning Economics