All the way back from Chapter One!
John Maynard Keynes had not entirely refuted the Classical model of the economy. Instead, he suggested it was just an (unlikely) special case of his General Theory. A special case in which prices and wages were able to fully adjust to changes in current and planned expenditure. Economists after Keynes, most notably Paul Samuelson, John Hicks, and Franco Modigliani, attempted to synthesize Keynes' dense book into a functional mathematical model from which conclusions can be drawn. Central to this new description of Keynesian ideas was time.
In the short run, prices and wages cannot adjust and are stuck in place.
In the long run, people have adequate time to make the appropriate adjustments and respond to the economic incentives.
Thus, the neoclassical synthesis built a bridge between the Keynesian school of thought and the Classical school of thought. It was Keynesian in the short run, and Classical in the long run.
"In the long run we are all dead. Economists set themselves too easy, too useless a task if, in tempestuous seasons, they can only tell us that when the storm is long past the ocean is flat again."
- John Maynard Keynes
Aggregate Demand represents the total amount of spending in the economy, relating the price level to the level of real GDP for that given amount of spending. For example, if you come back from the store and tell me you spent $100, there are many ways that could have gone down. Perhaps you only bought 2 things, and they cost $50 on average. Or maybe you bought 20 things and they cost $5 on average. Your aggregate demand was $100. How much stuff you got is your real GDP. And the average price of it all is the price level. Now just scale that concept up to represent the entire U.S. economy!
The proponents of the Neoclassical Synthesis argued that the Classical school of thought, which had fared poorly in the face of the Great Depression, still made sense. If people are doing their best when making economic choices, the "Invisible Hand" should make markets self-correcting. But the history of recessions showed that sometimes it takes people a fair bit of time to figure out what is best. In this framework, the Classical model still holds, but only in the long run.
While the Classical model is said to explain the long run, in the short run the Neoclassical Synthesis is decidedly Keynesian. Imperfect competition and human nature make input price, such as wages, resistant to downward pressure from deflation. Or, as we have said before, these prices and wages are sticky. If that is the case, then changes in the price level could create distortions in the economy which lead to overproduction or underproduction.
The Neoclassical model is focused on aggregate demand and aggregate supply. In the short run, aggregate supply is upward sloping due to sticky prices and wages. In the long run, aggregate supply is a vertical line, with no relationship between the price level and real GDP. With these pieces put together, we can use the AS/AD model to better understand the state of the economy, and make predictions about how it will respond to different events.
Now it is time to practice using the AS/AD model. This flow chart helps guide your thinking to match the workings of the model. Here are the steps for using it:
Determine if the scenario impacts Aggregate Demand or Aggregate Supply. There are keywords under each to help make this determination.
Proceed to the next decision. If AD, decided if the scenario results in less spending or more spending. If AD, determine if the scenario will impact long run aggregate supply, or just short run aggregate supply. Then determine the direction of the shift.
The AS/AD model was an important breakthrough for macroeconomics because it could be used to make predictions about how certain events would impact the economy. Economists could use it to forecast GDP like meteorologists use models to forecast the weather. Unlike the weather though, economic policy could then be used to change the forecast, and turn a rainy day into a day of sunshine!
Deeper Thoughts and Extra Practice
Example Question
Using estimates from economic data, economists believe the Phillips curve is best modeled by the equation:
Inflation Rate = 47/(Unemployment Rate)
Where both the inflation rate and the unemployment rate are entered in percentage form (e.g. 30.57 not 0.3057).
The economy is also in a recession, with real GDP currently at $13,390. Economists estimate potential GDP to be $18,066.
In response to the recession, the Federal Reserve has increased the money supply by 57%. Luckily, the velocity of money held steady at v = 1 and the economy recovered to full employment.
What is the natural rate of unemployment for this economy?
Put your answer in percentage form and round to two decimal places.
Hints: This question is super difficult! I hope it will be all the more satisfying to you when you figure it out. Here are some clues:
(1) Remember that M*V = P*Y, and we know V stays at 1, so it reduces to M = P*Y
(2) Inflation is the rate of change in the price level (P). So, Inflation = (P2 - P1)/P1
(3) You can rearrange the equation from (1) and note that P1 = M1/Y1 and P2 = M2/Y2
(4) You have Y1 and Y2 in the question. Think about it. And math tells us that M2/M1 has to equal 1+(growth in the money supply).
(5) You can use these clues to help you find the rate of inflation that brought the economy to full employment. Then use the Phillips Curve to find out what the rate of unemployment is.