Sikander Rahim

Rahim, Sikander “What use is the Neo-Classical Theory of International Trade?”, Lahore Journal of Economics, Parts I & II in volume 4, 1999.

What use is the Neo-Classical Theory of International Trade? Sikander Rahim

International economic policy is now more under the sway of orthodox economics than it has ever been. The main international economic institutions, the IMF, the World Bank, the WTO, and the major developed economies are unremitting advocates of free trade and impose their views on the developing countries. And the developing countries, whose attempts at economic development through protection have mostly failed, are on the whole inclined to accept these views. Over the last twenty years economic policy in these countries has more and more come to be formulated by-orthodox neo-classical economists, often described in the press as "reformers", who advocate more reliance on markets and less protection against imports.

Yet economic performance around the world has not been better over the last twenty years than it was in the earlier period of the 1950s, -60s and -70s. On the contrary, it has mostly been worse, the main exceptions being a few East Asian economies, including China, that have not on the whole been notable for the freedom of their markets or external trade, and, over the last ten years, the US. Economic growth rates of the world as a whole in the later period have been well below the rates of the earlier period. Income inequalities within countries have increased almost everywhere, except in the East Asian economies mentioned and possibly a few West European economies with large social protection systems.*In Latin America, .where liberalisation has been pursued with the most earnest, the bulk of the population appears to-be worse off than it was twenty years ago. Unemployment rates seem to have increased in most countries, except the successful East Asian economies and the US, and has become a major concern in the West European countries that have done best in containing income inequalities. International financial crises, if not more frequent than before, are severer and especially damaging to the developing countries. They include the debt crisis of the 1980s, the "peso" crisis of 1994-95. the East Asia crisis that began in 1997 and the present problems of Brazil and several other Latin American countries.

The notable exception in recent years to this deterioration has been the US, which has grown continuously over t(je last ten years and reduced its unemployment to the rates of the 1960s. Its success, though, is no evidence of the advantages of freer trade. The view popularised by some economists and the media, that it somehow indicates productivity growth caused by the freer markets and restructuring of firms, has no independentempirical support. If it were correct, productivity in the US would have been rising exceptionally fast, and would, therefore, be exceptionally high now. Yet detailed comparisons with other developed countries do not show productivity in the-US to be especially high.1 In contrast, the countries that are supposedly the greatest laggards in restructuring their firms, Germany and Japan, are consistently successful exporters and run large trade surpluses. Which means that production in the US has risen, not by some unusual acceleration of productivity, but in the usual way, through investment. Since the saving rate of the US has always been low by the standards of the developed countries and is now zero, it means that the investment has been financed by the rest of the world. This is apparent from the US balance of payments, which shows that the net inflow of capital to the US each year since the mid-1980s has, on average, been several times greater than the total gross inflow to the developing countries.2 Moreover, many developing countries are net exporters of capital to the US. To this must be added the great gains to the US from terms of trade movements in recent years, which have been mostly at the expense of the developing countries. For these developing countries, in particular, the economic performance of the US is not evidence that they will benefit from free trade.

A detached non-economist, observing that economic performance has been deteriorating around most of the world, might ask whether the theories by which economic policies are made might not be at fault. If the theories of international trade were expounded to him he would also be astonished by how little they explain and by how often they conflict with reality. And he would wonder how the main conclusions of the theories, that free trade is in some sense optimal, can be so confidently asserted when the empirical evidence is so much against the theories themselves. In ' a natural science a theory is 'not accepted until it has been tested empirically and, when the wellbeing of people can be seriously affected, notably in medicine, procedures and products are tested to ensure their efficacy and to ascertain their side-effects before they can be used. Economics is different: the optimality of free trade asserted by neo-classical trade theory is inherently untestable, being a comparison between the welfare of people in two alternative states; theories of international trade either conflict with reality or take forms thaf are too general to be tested, and side effects are rarely acknowledged. Nevertheless, the economist cangive, even impose, advice on the basis of these theories, though it affects whole countries.

The purpose of this article is to show that the non-economist's doubts are justified. It is in two parts. The first describes some of the failures of orthodox neo-classical theories of international trade to predict or describe the patterns of tiade around the world and the consequences of applying politics that derive from them, and it shows that these failures are the consequences of unsound reasoning and incoherence in the theories. The second part, to appear in a later issue of this Journal, is intended to show that a simpler and more realistic approach to constructing a theory accommodates and explains the phenomena that neo-classical theory can not.