Informal labor markets in low- and middle-income countries are characterized by high unemployment and job turnover, despite high labor demand. I conduct three field experiments to examine how frictions arising from wage theft, worker reneging and liquidity constraints lead to a mismatch in workers' labor supply and firms' labor demand in these markets. In the first experiment, 1,360 workers receive real job offers on either flat contracts (paid daily), which reduce wage theft concerns and worker liquidity constraints, or back-loaded contracts (paid at end of contract), which don't. To isolate the effects of wage theft concerns I cross-randomize these contracts with an insurance contract. I find that labor supply is three times larger for flat contracts. This preference is driven by workers' fears of wage theft by firms (28\%), liquidity constraints (22\%), and demand for flexibility to break contracts (50\%). This flexibility captures an option value, protecting workers from income loss in the event of future shocks or excess work exaction by firms under back-loaded contracts. The costs of these frictions are high—72\% of workers who reject job offers end up earning less income than those offers would have provided. In the second experiment, I make real offers to hire workers on either flat or back-loaded contracts to 349 firms. The firms' labor demand doubles for back-loaded contracts, driven by liquidity constraints (37\%) and costs associated with worker reneging (63\%) in flat contracts. In a third experiment, firms and workers who accepted contracts in the first two experiments are matched with each other. Workers are 69\% more likely to complete back-loaded contracts compared to flat contracts, which have a completion rate of 34\% and thereby impose significant costs on firms. Firms exact longer working hours from workers in back-loaded contracts, validating the workers' concerns. My findings suggest that improving contract enforcement and providing credit to firms can reduce welfare losses in equilibrium and improve efficiency.
Millions of workers in low- and middle-income countries seek low-skilled employment through informal spot markets in urban areas. Using detailed micro-data from spot markets in India, this paper examines firm–worker wage negotiations and the determinants of undercutting behavior. Despite high unemployment, workers undercut each other in only 27% of negotiations. The likelihood of undercutting varies systematically with contract type, which is strongly correlated with job type: multi-task jobs are predominantly offered under fixed-hour contracts, while single-task jobs are typically offered under Fixed Work contracts, where pay is based on task completion regardless of hours worked. Workers are nearly twice as likely to undercut in negotiations for Fixed Work contracts compared to Fixed Hour contracts. We explain this pattern using a model in which workers’ reservation wages depend on the value of leisure, with effort choices, shaped by ability, determining attainable leisure time. This mechanism generates greater dispersion in reservation wages for contracts without fixed hours. The model predicts, and the data confirm, that undercutting is more likely for jobs in which the reservation wage distribution is more dispersed, as measured by the variance. These findings shed light on wage-setting mechanisms in low-wage labor markets and show how job characteristics and workers’ belief structures jointly shape negotiation outcomes.
We study the distributional consequences of colonial institutions by analyzing the effect of direct and indirect rule on the outcomes of historically disadvantaged and advantaged caste groups across the border of Hyderabad, the largest princely state in colonial India, using a border discontinuity design. We find that disadvantaged caste groups in indirectly ruled areas have 1.4 fewer years of schooling and significantly less wealth than similar groups in direct rule areas. A similar analysis for Advantaged caste suggests that they have less wealth and small but insignificant differences in education. Cross-caste wealth inequality and land inequality are higher in indirectly ruled areas. Differences in extent of agricultural labor repression, as measured by agricultural wages and bonded labor, led to the emergence of these differences during the colonial era. Differential growth in credit institutions after independence negatively affected productivity in indirectly ruled areas. As a result, farmers in these areas have larger non-institutional debt than directly ruled areas, and disadvantaged caste farmers drive this effect.
Environmental Degradation in One's Own Backyard: Who Gains and Who Loses from Sand Mining in India (with Sushant Banjara, Claire Fan)
Sand, the backbone of modern construction, makes up 85% of global mineral extraction. Its large-scale removal—especially from fragile river ecosystems—has raised serious environmental concerns, particularly in developing countries experiencing construction booms and lacking strong environmental regulation. Yet, the full extent of these effects, their social and economic consequences, and how they are distributed across communities remain poorly understood. This project combines novel administrative data with satellite imagery in a difference-in-differences framework to estimate the causal impacts of sand mining in Bihar, India. We find that sand mining increases flood inundation rates and flood frequency by 1.5 and 2 percentage points, respectively, from a baseline of 10%. Agricultural output, measured by vegetation index, declines by 5%. Despite these environmental costs, sand mining raises local income—proxied by nightlight intensity—by 10–20% in nearby villages. Income gains are broadly distributed within villages, reaching both ex-ante wealthier and poorer households, but are concentrated among socially dominant groups, particularly upper castes and OBCs. These findings help explain why sand mining continues with local support despite environmental harm and regulatory efforts. The unequal balance of economic benefits on social groups highlights the need for targeted policies—those that mitigate flooding, ensure sustainable mining, and compensate marginalized communities bearing the brunt of net harm.
The Direct and Spillover Impacts of Gender Quotas in Public Sector Employment (with Niharika Singh)
Social Engineering through Schools (with Anirvan Chaudhary, Aaditya Dar, Chinmaya Kumar)