Publications
Dylan R. Clarke and Adam Metzler. “Estimating the Delay of Criminal Trials: Evidence from Canada.” (2025) Journal of Law & Empirical Analysis 2(1): 33-59 [SSRN] [DOI]
Court congestion is among society’s oldest legal problems; protections from it are enshrined in constitutions around the world. This paper uses publicly available data on the duration of millions of criminal court cases over the course of two decades across Canadian provinces to analyze the performance of the criminal justice system using queueing theory. Our new approach to estimating the delay of criminal trials appropriately includes the time from the point the charges are laid to first appearance, which is not available in raw data. We find that the queue sizes and wait times are growing in many provinces, suggesting that the criminal justice system is approaching, or perhaps beyond, capacity. Using several different time series specifications, we find that the utilization rate and model-implied queue size co-move positively with the population in pretrial custody. The results suggest that court congestion, as measured by statistics from queueing theory, has explanatory power for the rising population in pretrial custody.
This paper develops a model in which housing incurs a property damage for which the tenant must sue in order to be made whole. The model is analyzed under both market rents and rent control regimes, as well as for tenants with limited wealth, bilateral (tenant) investment, coinsurance, and rent abatement. The model facilitates the evaluation of several policies, such as rent control, landlord-tenant laws, income redistribution, tenant insurance, and rent abatement. The model makes several predictions which are consistent with empirical findings in housing economics, such as how and why rent control decreasing investment in maintenance, why the poor occupy housing of worse condition, and how laws shifting liability onto the landlord increase the quality of housing for poor tenants as well as increase rent prices. It also nests classic hypotheses, such as the Calabresi’s efficiency of strict liability rules and the least cost avoider, in addition to clarifications on Friedman’s prediction that rent control decreases investment.
Dylan R. Clarke and Daniel E. Gold. “The Effects of Residential Landlord-Tenant Laws: New Evidence from Canadian Reforms using Census Data.” Journal of Urban Economics, Vol. 140 (March 2024): 103631 [SSRN] [DOI]
We study the consequences of landlord-tenant laws on quality and prices in the rental housing market. We use the staggered introduction of Canadian Residential Tenancy Acts to study the consequences of a landlord-tenant reform that reduced tenants' litigation costs and improved their bargaining power through mandatory contractual terms. To do so, we employ a the difference-in-differences approach to estimate the average treatment effect on a repeated-cross section of households, controlling for income and family structure in five cities. The estimates imply that the reform led to a decline of 2.2 percentage points in the probability of a major defect, with no measurable effect on rent prices or homeownership rates. The average treatment effects are concentrated within families with children who face greater costs to moving in response to property damage and are least sensitive to changes in the vacancy rate. The results are consistent with a stylized model in which a reduction in litigation costs allows the tenant to more cheaply recover on damages when moving costs are high, with second-generation rent controls limiting increases in rent prices charged by the landlord.
Working Papers
Deference by courts to democratically elected legislature is at the heart of our constitutional democracy. This paper analyzes a novel database of the universe of cases involving the judicial review of legislation from the inception of the Charter to present. Deference increased sharply as the Charter was introduced, but has been steadily decreasing since 2000 with the McLachlin and Wagner courts. I find that this fall in deference is concentrated among penal statutes, consistent with the prediction set out in Irwin Toy. With the newly constructed judge-level data, I am able to analyze the percentage of cases in which individual members of the court invalidate legislation across various rights involving penal consequences, free expression, labour rights and equality, as well as upon the inclusion of case fixed effects. The recent fall in judicial deference can largely be attributed to certain Liberal appointees striking down more penal statutes due to both construing rights of the accused more broadly and, as predicted by Irwin Toy, finding that the least intrusive means have not been taken. The judge-level data also provide insights on differences (or lack thereof) in judicial behaviour across sex and politics.
Hamlet Qua Witness. [SSRN] (Submitted)
It is tradition in law schools across the world to put Hamlet on trial, often with him invoking some sort of insanity defense, for mistakenly killing Polonius in the Queen's closet in Act 3 Scene 4 of Hamlet. This line of inquiry is second-best. The defense of mental disorder is too sui generis of a regime to be adapted to the facts of Hamlet. We should instead put Claudius on trial with Hamlet as witness. I re-interpret the play through a recent performance at the Stratford Festival in the summer of 2022, which deployed Hamlet and Polonius as 'lawful espials' (3.1.35) on Claudius's confession and played heavily on Hamlet's feigned insanity. I draw a comparison between the famous 'O, my offence is rank' (3.3.40) soliloquy and the recent case of R v. Schneider, 2022 SCC 34 in which the Supreme Court of Canada split 7-2 on whether a similar such party admission statement would be relatively more logically probative than potentially prejudicial. Hamlet's 'madness,' while ostensibly feigned but for his melancholy evidenced in the 'to be, or not to be' (3.1.64) soliloquy, has much to teach us about the weight of demeanour relative to mistakenness in the way the law of evidence evaluates credibility. To epistemically prejudice Hamlet for his behaviour after losing his father in the play is to fail to track the truth in Hamlet. However, the Prince doesn't quite meet the standards set out for witnesses in Toohey or Vetrovec. I dub these mildly unreliable narrators on the stand as “Hamlet witnesses.” Both Freud and Goethe's interpretations suggest Hamlet is a perfectly competent and credible witness. Hamlet's belief-forming process over the party admission statement is reliable and responsible despite his other possible frailties and in light of his virtues.
This Essay develops an economic approach to statutory and contractual interpretation. The economic approach to interpretation understands "things" as inherently economic objects that drafters intend to specify to include close-to-perfect substitutes or similar fairly priced items by the market. Several difficult cases involving exclusivity clauses, the exchange of land, and options contracts are resolved using economic and financial theory. The economic approach offers an alternative to the dictionary that offers more pleasing answers than the extant approach taken by courts which can easily arrive at incorrect conclusions. The economic approach has applications to contractual interpretation, but also areas of public law, such as competition law, taxation law, and international trade law.
Admission of surreptitious interceptions done by non-State agents into evidence in criminal proceedings constitutes a State action which engages the constitutional right to be free from unreasonable search and seizure. As a result, a host of criminal statutes which allow for disclosure in criminal proceedings, such as parts of s. 193(2)(a) of the Criminal Code and 720 ILCS 5/14-3(i), are unconstitutional as-applied. The new section 8 jurisprudence in Lambert and Bykovets emphasizes that the violation of a reasonable expectation of privacy constitutes a “search” and the act of the police to possess such evidence constitutes a “seizure” within the meaning of s. 8 of the Charter. A reasonable and probable grounds or probable cause standard is constitutionally required for admissibility of warrantless surreptitious interceptions in which not all parties consent and there exists a reasonable expectation of privacy. The remedy of inadmissibility is supported on grounds of privacy, for which the tort remedy may be inappropriate, and, somewhat counterintuitively, free expression, so as to protect private speech which facilitates democratic processes, a robust epistemic marketplace, and self-expression. Such a broad exclusionary rule may require exemptions to pass constitutional muster, as it violates ss. 7 and 11(d) of the Charter for defense offers, making exemptions for officer-involved interactions and exigent circumstances, too, constitutionally required.
The Uneasy Case for Contributory Negligence.
Tax Equity and the View to Profit.
Narrow in the Reus.