Research
Working papers:
Recognition Probability in Legislative Bargaining, with Natalie Lee (paper, also available at SSRN) Conditionally Accepted at the Journal of Experimental Political Science
In legislative bargaining, the proposer is often able to extract a greater proportion of the surplus. However, a higher likelihood of being selected as the proposer can backfire, as it may reduce the probability that the agent is included in a winning coalition. We experimentally test the theoretical prediction of potentially negative returns to recognition probability in two-period legislative bargaining noted in Baron & Ferejohn (1989).
We find that higher recognition probability benefits subjects in all treatments, except one in which we automate the second period. It is because proposers often favor the member with the greater recognition probability as a coalition partner, and such tendency varies depending on the proposer’s recognition probability, counter to the theoretical prediction. In all treatments, a vast majority of subjects exhibit a strict preference for higher recognition probability
Identity-Based Elections, with Helios Herrera (paper) (earlier version: CEPR DP17203)
We develop a novel notion of political partisanship based on identity preservation. Partisans wish to convince themselves that their party is the better choice. They select information sources from a broad array of media outlets with different biases in order to achieve that goal, but they may not always succeed due to their rationality which acts as a constraint. Thus, citizens of opposing political camps tend to consume different media diets and hold divergent beliefs, as in the U.S. We show how asymmetries between the two political sides skew electoral outcomes and generate information aggregation failures despite rationality. Here we consider salient examples such as asymmetric exposure to or asymmetric trust in media, as well as propaganda, but this notion of partisanship is applicable to a wide variety of contexts.
Group Bargaining and Delegation, with WonSeok Yoo (available at SSRN)
Two groups engaged in non-cooperative bargaining over a fixed surplus may differ in size and the supermajority threshold they employ for within-group ratification. A group may also delegate the ability to propose allocations to a subset of members. We find that total allocation to a group does not depend on group size and increases with the supermajority threshold. Within-group inequality is an increasing function of group size and decreases with the supermajority threshold. Finally, we find that delegation decreases the group’s total allocation because non-delegates accept lower allocations. We consider the implications of our results on bilateral treaty negotiation.
Optimal Differentiation through Step-wise Learning (paper)
I consider the problem of an entrant to an industry with a present incumbent, both vying to sell to a continuum of consumers. The ideal product designs for each consumer in this environment are distributed over an n-dimensional space. The entrant must first learn about the locations of consumers and then design a product. While the entrant can freely design her product, the incumbent has a valence advantage that the entrant must take into account. The valence advantage for the incumbent drives horizontal product differentiation because if the entrant chooses a product design too close to the incumbent, she will not sell to any consumers.
I find that the entrant differentiates her product only as much as is needed to counteract the valence advantage of the incumbent. I also find that the optimal differentiation follows a predictable pattern that depends upon the strength of the incumbent. Against a weak (strong) incumbent, the entrant differentiates along dimensions with less (greater) expected variance, and less (greater) salience. Further, I show that the returns to research regarding consumer preferences along any dimension are initially convex, but must eventually become concave. Therefore, step-wise learning and specialization is optimal in this environment.
Career Concerns with Cost Uncertainty (paper)
I consider a finite-horizon continuous-time career concerns model. As in Holmstrom (1999), there is symmetric uncertainty about a worker's ability. Additionally, the worker has private information about her cost of effort. The sequence of observed outputs allows learning about both attributes of the worker. Similar to other career concerns models, incentives to exert effort are driven in part by a signal-jamming motive, i.e., the desire to manipulate the market's beliefs about the worker's ability. This motive is present throughout the worker's lifetime, but its impact on worker effort gradually decreases over time as the market learns the worker's ability. In contrast, the motive to signal effort cost is more nuanced, and changes sign as time progresses. I find that early in her career, effort cost uncertainty pushes the worker to work harder to signal that she is has a low effort cost (is cost-efficient). During her middle and late career, the worker has an incentive to signal that she has a high effort cost (is cost-inefficient). These incentives to signal effort cost types are driven by the implication the effort cost type has on the market's posteriors regarding the worker's ability type. In the second phase of her career, the worker lowers her effort to seem like the cost-inefficient type. During her late-career, surprisingly, the worker increases her effort to signal to the market that she is cost-inefficient. While the focus of this paper remains theoretical, this paper suggests empirical implications and applications. The key applications considered are regarding the estimation of wages as a function of years of experience, the distribution of outputs, and performance-based pay.
In progress:
Optimal Policy Choice and Campaign Financing, with Amy Hongfei Sun
We build a model in which two office-motivated candidates strategically choose policies while two policy-motivated large donors strategically choose how much to give. Voter ideal points are distributed over the policy space and they either abstain or vote non-strategically for the closer candidate. Candidates use own and donated funds to drive turnout. Donors give to candidates in close races and with more extreme positions. Self-funded candidates need to raise less outside funding and may choose more moderate positions.
Partisan Credulity and Fake News, with Helios Herrera
Some Non-Monotonicities in Finite-Period Legislative Bargaining , with WonSeok Yoo
The Power of the Agenda Setter: A Dynamic Legislative Bargaining Game, with Ewout Verriest (paper)
We consider an infinitely repeated legislative bargaining game with three players who split a fixed surplus in every period. The status quo allocation evolves endogenously over time, as agents can approve new proposals by simple majority rule. One player is permanently endowed with veto power, and must approve any amendment to the status quo. The veto player's recognition probability is defined as the probability (p) that she is randomly selected as the agenda setter in a given period. First, we characterize symmetric Markov Perfect Equilibria for all possible primitives, and show that there exists a threshold value of p below which the veto player can asymptotically extract the full surplus, by offering a sequence of alternating bribes to each of her opponents whenever she is selected as the proposer (as in Nunnari (2019)). Beyond this threshold, however, we show existence of other MPEs with only partial surplus extraction, in which non-veto players can sustain strictly positive surplus shares in the long run by forming a permanent blocking coalition against the veto player. Assuming no agent has commitment power, we show that the partial extraction MPE is unique after applying a coalition-proofness refinement. In comparative statics, we show that cooperation between non-veto players is more likely to be sustainable if agents are more patient and if the initial status quo division is more egalitarian. In ongoing work, we show that our MPE is robust to having an arbitrary odd number of players. Our findings imply that a sufficiently patient and powerful veto player (e.g. a monarch with a high recognition probability) may have an incentive to cede some of her agenda-setting power to her non-veto opponents (e.g. the bourgeoisie and nobility), through a voluntary “democratization” process which permanently lowers p.