The figure shows the response of 30-year mortgage rates (by the date the deed is signed) to shocks in 10-year swap rates computed around FOMC announcements separating between positive (red triangles) and negative shocks (blue circles).
Monetary Policy Wedges and the Long-term Liabilities of Households and Firms, with Jules Van Binsbergen.
Abstract
We examine the impact of monetary policy transmission on households’ and firms’ long-duration liabilities using high-frequency variation in 10-year swap rates around FOMC announcements. We find that mortgage rates respond about three weeks after monetary policy announcements, with a larger response to interest rate hikes compared to cuts in post-2010 data. The strong response of mortgage rates to 10- year swap rates leaves little explanatory power for mortgage concentration or bank market power. Corporate yields respond symmetrically to positive and negative shocks, with a higher sensitivity for firms with lower credit ratings. We show that expected future short rates and interbank market frictions play a significant role in explaining both mortgage rates and corporate bond yields. While the term premium correlates positively with mortgage rates, it has little comovement with corporate bond yields.
The figure shows the contact pattern over time for the government of Turkey. A contact is defined as a year-month with at least one meeting between a foreign country and a representative. Each dot in the figure represents a contact. Republican legislators are shown as red squares, democrats as blue circles, and independents as violet triangles. The vertical axis is the DW-nominate score from Pool and Rosenthal (2011). The shaded area in the background is blue if democrats had the majority in the Senate.
Foreign Influence in U.S. politics, with Max Miller and S.Lakshmi Naaraayanan. Online Appendix available here. An easy-to-read summary
Abstract
We document that foreign lobbying shapes US government spending and public policy. We introduce a comprehensive dataset of 180,000 date-stamped, in-person meetings between foreign agents and individual US legislators, spanning 2000 to 2018 and covering 146 countries and 1,200 legislators. We find that (1) meetings are positively related to legislator lawmaking effectiveness and membership to foreign affairs committee and (2) foreign agents maintain connections with legislators even after they depart from important committees. Around these meetings, (3) foreign countries benefit from increased financial aid and advantageous product tariffs and (4) foreign firms whose governments lobby more often benefit from larger subsidies and US government contracts. Finally, we study benefits and costs accruing to legislators and show (5) monetary and electoral benefits, but no evidence that US legislators are punished by their constituents because they meet with representatives of foreign countries.
Articles published in refereed journals (and forthcoming)
The expected default frequency of firms repaying their debt (solid line) versus the firms issuing more debt (dashed line).
Cyclical dispersion in expected defaults, with Joao Gomes and Jessica Wachter, Review of Financial Studies, 32 (4), pp. 1275-1308, April 2019. Online Appendix available here. Working paper available here.
Abstract
A growing literature shows that credit indicators forecast aggregate real outcomes. While researchers have proposed various explanations, the economic mechanism behind these results remains an open question. In this paper, we show that a simple, frictionless, model explains empirical findings commonly attributed to credit cycles. Our key assumption is that firms have heterogeneous exposures to underlying economy-wide shocks. This leads to endogenous dispersion in credit quality that varies over time and predicts future excess returns and real outcomes.
Comparison of 12-month zero-coupon interest rates implied from SPX options (blue line) with government bond rates (red line) and LIBOR rates (yellow line).
Risk-free Interest Rates, with Jules Van Binsbergen and William Diamond, Journal of Financial Economics, 142 (3), pp. 1-29, January 2022 (lead article). Working paper available here.
Abstract
We estimate risk-free interest rates unaffected by convenience yields on safe assets. We infer them from risky asset prices without relying on any specific model of risk. We obtain a term structure of convenience yields with maturities up to 2.5 years at a minutely frequency. The convenience yield on treasuries equals about 40 basis points, is larger below 3 months maturity, and quadruples during the financial crisis. In high-frequency event studies, conventional and unconventional monetary stimulus reduce convenience yields, particularly during the crisis. We further study convenience-yield-free CIP deviations, and we show significant bond return predictability related to convenience yields.
Intraday evolution of the EUR/USD exchange rate on July 31, 2019. The shaded area denotes the FOMC press conference. The red dotted lines highlight the time in which the Chairman mentioned “midcycle adjustment to policy.”
Real-time Price Discovery via Verbal Communication: Method and Application to Fedspeak, with Roberto Gomez Cram. Journal of Financial Economics, 143 (3), pp. 993-1025, March 2022. Working paper available here.
Abstract
We study the price discovery process during FOMC days. For several asset classes we find that price movements around the post-meeting statement release are strong predictors of price movements around the subsequent press conference. The correlation is as high as 58% for medium-term Eurodollar futures and 44% for the S&P 500 index. We then use press-conference videos, timestamp the words pronounced, and align them with high-frequency financial data. Minutes in which the Chairman discusses changes in the newly-issued policy statement lie behind the positive correlation. We discuss several potential explanations and consider the implications of our findings for asset pricing and monetary economics.
Average profitability pattern for the two extreme lobbying portfolios 12 quarters before sorting to 12 quarters after sorting (time t). Profitability is gross profits over lagged assets. Persuasives are firms in top lobbying quintile, while feebles are firms in the bottom quintile. Time-0 profitability is standardized to 1.
Follow the money, Online Appendix available here. Review of Economic Studies, 91(2), pp. 1122-1161, March 2024 (Featured Article).Working paper available here.
Abstract
I study, both empirically and theoretically, the economic and financial consequences of corporate lobbying. Firms lobby politicians to increase their share of government contracts, but political competition creates firm-level risk, inflating their cost of capital and reducing their incentive to invest in research and development (R&D). I document an annual 6%–8% return premium for stocks of high-lobbying firms, which compensates investors for political risk. An estimated model in which firms can lobby and innovate and investors are risk averse replicates key features of corporate lobbying in the US, including the well-established paradox that lobbying contributions are small relative to the policies at stake. The model predicts that if investors ceased seeking compensation for political risk, R&D investment would increase by 6% and the innovation rate by 0.4 percentage points. The risk-premium costs of lobbying are quantitatively and economically important even if the resources “wasted” on lobbying are objectively small.
Average frequency of a financial crisis for each quintile of the growth in the ratio of total loans to GDP between year t-5 and t. Data are a cross section of 17 developed countries.
Foreseen Risks, with Joao Gomes and Jessica Wachter. Online Appendix available here. Journal of Economic Theory, 212, September 2023. Working paper available here.
Abstract
Financial crises tend to follow rapid credit expansions. Causality, however, is far from obvious. We show how this pattern arises naturally when financial intermediaries optimally exploit economic rents that drive their franchise value. As this franchise value varies over the business cycle, so too do the incentives to engage in risky lending. The model leads to novel insights on the effects of recent unconventional monetary policies in developed economies. We argue that bank lending might have responded less than expected to these interventions because they enhanced franchise value, inadvertently encouraging banks to pursue safer investments in low-risk government securities.
The figure plots the predicted 20-year dynamics of markup for three automobile companies. Forecasts are made as of 2015. Solid lines represent forecasts made from our benchmark model including the information from market-to-book ratios and the past two values of markup growth, while dashed lines shows the forecasts using only lagged markups in an AR(2) model.
The present value of future market power, with Thummim Cho, Lukas Kremens, Howard Kung. Forthcoming. Review of Financial Studies.
Abstract
We introduce a present-value identity relating a firm's market value to expected future markups, output growth, discount rates, and investments. Distinguishing current from expected markups reveals five empirical facts: (i) Expected markups account for half the rise in U.S. firm values since 1980. (ii) The rise in aggregate expected markups reflects market-share reallocation towards high-expected-markup firms and within-firm increases. (iii) Expected markups are linked to intangible investments. (iv) They relate negatively to discount rates over time but (v) positively to abnormal returns across firms. Finally, variation in long-term expected markups is primarily associated with asset prices rather than current markups.
The figure shows the heatmap by grid cells (810m × 810m grids) for the RSEI cancer scores aggregated for toxic chemicals released by Brenner Tank LLC, Fond du Lac, WI 54935, in 2002.
The impact of carcinogenic risk exposure on housing values: Estimates from chemical reclassifications, with Jules Van Binsbergen, Joao Cocco and S.Lakshmi Naaraayanan. Conditionally accepted. Review of Financial Studies.
Abstract
We quantify the impact of perceived cancer risk on housing values using widely-advertised national reclassifications of chemical carcinogenicity in the United States. Combining these information events with an empirical design that compares changes in house values closer to affected toxic plants against those farther away isolates the effect of cancer risk news from other local factors. Focusing on plants previously emitting reclassified carcinogenic chemicals, we estimate a 1-2% decline in housing values within a 3-mile radius compared to those located farther away. The effects are stronger in areas with higher media presence underscoring the role of salience as a mechanism.