Crisis for Beginners

Some of the people who make this site are beginners too, so here are some of the texts we find most helpful in first getting a hold on what's going on.

Recent Posts

  • Mattick: "What is to be done?" final part of 4-part series in brooklyn rail "What is to be done?" (Pt 4 of 4) by Paul Mattick
    Posted Apr 20, 2009, 11:01 AM by franqui coat
  • Mattick: "Ups and Downs – The Economic Crisis (pt. 3)" Part 3 in a series of articles published in the Brooklyn Rail, this installment provides a clear but comprehensive historical analysis of crisis along with a crash course on ...
    Posted Feb 25, 2009, 8:50 AM by John Clegg
  • Josef K: "A Brief History of the Crisis" A concise background to the current financial crisis and recession.However it may seem, the current crisis didn’t come out of nowhere. Following WWII, the government and employers were ...
    Posted Feb 4, 2009, 2:03 PM by franqui coat
  • Cramer: "Invisible Hand” Ideology and “Underconsumption” Mythology “Invisible Hand” Ideology and “Underconsumption” Mythology   Testifying before Congress (10/24/08), former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan said we each have an ideology that guides us in understanding and ...
    Posted Nov 16, 2008, 10:54 AM by John Clegg
  • A House of Cards, from fantasy finance to global crash A House of Cards from fantasy finance to global crash by Gerry Gold & Paul FeldmanAn 82 page pamphlet that succinctly introduces many of the Marxian concepts employed on this ...
    Posted Nov 12, 2008, 12:13 PM by John Clegg
  • Ramaa Vasudevan - Financialization: A Primer Very short primer from Dollars & Sense:http://brechtforum.org/economywatch/financialization-primer?bc=
    Posted Sep 14, 2009, 10:10 AM by John Clegg
  • Mary Lynn Cramer: "Their Assets, Our Debts" and "Economic Amnesia" Two clearly written articles by Mary Lynn Cramer giving an historical background to the crisis as well as explaining the limits of mainstream economic interpretations of it."Their Assets, Our ...
    Posted Oct 29, 2008, 6:15 AM by John Clegg
  • Richard Wolff: "Capitalist Crisis, Marx's Shadow" Richard Wolff: "Capitalist Crisis, Marx's Shadow". A good clear introduction to the crisis. Argues that it is a delayed result of a 1970s underconsumptionist crisis. See also the video ...
    Posted Nov 12, 2008, 4:44 PM by John Clegg
  • Amehurst economists on the Market Meltdown text and videos from UMass Amehurst Econ professors, explaining the crisis in very basic terms: Market Meltdown 101
    Posted Oct 15, 2008, 8:18 PM by John Clegg
  • Paul Mattick Jnr: "Up in Smoke" and "Risky Business" A series of articles for the Brooklyn Rail introducing the crisis for lay readers.part 1 "Up in Smoke"part 2 "Risky Business"
    Posted Nov 11, 2008, 2:15 PM by John Clegg
Showing posts 1 - 10 of 10. View more »

Mattick: "What is to be done?" final part of 4-part series in brooklyn rail

posted Apr 20, 2009, 10:59 AM by franqui coat

Mattick: "Ups and Downs – The Economic Crisis (pt. 3)"

posted Feb 4, 2009, 1:55 PM by franqui coat   [ updated Feb 25, 2009, 8:50 AM by John Clegg ]

Part 3 in a series of articles published in the Brooklyn Rail, this installment provides a clear but comprehensive historical analysis of crisis along with a crash course on theories of money and the rate of profit.

Ups and Downs: The Economic Crisis (pt. 3)


As last year’s economic slowdown turned into a financial crisis, and the financial crisis into a global recession, there has been more and more reference to the Great Depression of the 1930s, as well as to the less severe downturns that have punctuated the decades since World War II. There is little mention, however, of the fact that business depressions have been a recurrent feature of the capitalist economy since the early nineteenth century, inspiring a vast literature of theoretical attempts to understand them and statistical materials for identifying and tracking them.

Perhaps the venerable concept of the “business cycle” makes few appearances in current economic commentary in part because post-war downturns were mild and short in comparison to earlier ones (economic history from the early 1800s to the late 1930s was about equally divided between prosperity and depressions, which became deeper and longer over time). The claims of Keynesian economists, after 1945, to have ended the business cycle by “fine-tuning” the economy with governmental controls did not survive the combination of inflation and stagnation that set in the 1970s. Yet the ability of the economy to bounce back quickly from hard times led newly confident “neoliberal” economists to insist that capitalism is simply prosperous by nature.

In reality, the current worldwide slump, far from a mysterious anomaly, represents the return of the capitalist economy to the dark side of its pre-World War II history.

Photos of Bushwick by Miller Oberlin.

The boom-bust cycle started up as soon as the growth of a money-centered economy and the Industrial Revolution led to the establishment of capitalism in wide enough swaths of territory for it to become the dominant social system. Before that, of course, economic life was disrupted by a variety of disturbances: war, plague, bad harvests. But the coming of capitalism brought something new: starvation alongside good harvests and mountains of food; idle factories and unemployed workers in peacetime despite need for the goods they produced. Such breakdowns in the normal process of production, distribution, and consumption were now due not to natural or political but to specifically economic factors: lack of money to purchase needed goods, profits too low to make production worthwhile. Major downturns have been identified in every decade from the 1820s forward, increasing steadily in seriousness up to the Big One in 1929. All of these moments saw declines in industrial production, sharp rises in unemployment, falling wages (and other prices), and failures of financial institutions, preceded or followed by financial panics and credit crunches. In every case, the downturn was eventually followed by a return to greater levels of production (and employment) than before. At first only the most capitalistically developed nations were affected (the 1825 crisis took in only Great Britain and the United States). But over the next hundred years, as capitalism spread across the world and countries were increasingly linked by trade and capital movements, the cycle of crisis and recovery took in ever more areas, although not all experienced these phases in the same way, to the same extent, or at the same moment.

While early-19th century champions of the free market—the ancestors of today’s neoliberals—insisted that a general crisis of the economic system (as opposed to temporary disequilibria) is simply impossible, other economists responded to the evidence by speculating as to the causes of the cyclical pattern. The fact that in a market economy decisions about where to invest money and so about what is produced, and in what quantities, are made prior to finding out what quantities of particular goods are actually wanted by consumers, and at what price, seems obviously relevant to recurrent fluctuations in economic activity, in which different parts of a complex system adjust to each other over time. Another basic aspect of capitalism—that the total money value of goods produced must be greater than the total money paid out in wages in order for profit to exist—suggests an inherent imbalance between production and eventual consumption. As both of these are constant features of this society, however, it is hard to see how they can explain the alternation between periods of growth and collapses serious enough, on occasion, to give large numbers of people the idea that the system was actually breaking down. Economists searched for explanations lying outside the economy proper, such as sunspots, whose cyclical increase and diminution seemed to match the economic data closely, and might conceivably affect the economy through effects on agriculture. Other theories looked at waves of optimism and pessimism, perhaps caused by changes in death rates, to explain increases and decreases in business investment.

A more plausible explanation of the cyclical pattern, in terms of the changing profitability of investment, emerged from the major survey of economic data carried out over many decades at the National Bureau of Economic Research in Washington by economist Wesley C. Mitchell and his associates. Profit—I quote Mitchell’s words, but it is a commonplace concept—is “the difference between the prices which an enterprise pays for all the things it must buy, and the prices which the enterprise receives for all the things it sells.” Since a business enterprise must regularly turn a profit to continue to prosper, “the making of profits is of necessity the controlling aim of business management” and decisions about where to invest and so what to produce are regulated by the quest for profit. At some times businesses do better across the economy as a whole, earning more profit on the average, than at other times. And when average profits are high society enjoys prosperity, but declining profits can lead to depression.

What determines these changes in the profitability of capital investment? This question—which Mitchell did not really answer—bears not only on capitalists’ expectations and so their willingness to invest funds, but also on their ability to invest, since the money available for investment is either drawn from existing profits or borrowed against future profits, which must then come into existence if loans are to be repaid. The question as to the average size of profits produced at any time, just because it is so basic, takes us to the heart of the economic system. As Mitchell explained the regulation of business decisions by the need for profit, “industry is subordinated to business, the making of goods to the making of money.” But what determines the size of the difference between money costs and sales prices that is collected as profit?

To quote Mitchell once more, in a modern business economy, “most … economic activities have taken on the form of making and spending money.” We are so used to this state of affairs that we hardly notice its historical peculiarity and forget that in the past—in much of the world, even the very recent past—most people produced much or most of their own food, clothing, and other necessities of life. So it is worth while remembering that, while money appears in many types of society, capitalism is the only one in which it plays a central role in the production and distribution of goods and services, so that nearly every object and service that we make use of in the course of a day has had to be purchased for money.

Money is basic to capitalism because this is the first social system in which most productive activity—apart from the few tasks that people still perform for themselves, like (sometimes) cooking dinner, brushing their teeth, or hobbies—is wage labor, performed in exchange for money. Most people, lacking access to land, tools, and raw materials, or enough money to purchase these, cannot produce the goods—housing, clothes, food—they need; they must work for others who have the money to hire them as well as to supply materials and tools. This money flows back to the employers when employees purchase goods they—as a class—have produced. Meanwhile, employers buy and sell goods—raw materials, machinery, consumer goods—from and to each other. Thus flows of money connect all the individuals involved in one social system.

The people who produce goods for a business have no direct relationship with the people who will buy and consume those goods or services, even though it is ultimately for these consumers that they are producing. The workers in bakeries and automobile factories do not know who will buy the bread and the cars they make, or what quantities they want and can afford. The same is true of their employers. Though capitalist businesses produce to meet the needs of anyone who can pay, as the property of individuals or corporations they are linked to the rest of society only by the exchange of goods for money, when they buy materials and labor and when they sell their products. This is why each business only finds out from its success or failure in selling its products, at sufficiently high prices to make a profit, to what extent it is meeting the needs of customers. It is only when products are sold and consumed that the labor that has made them counts as part of the total work performed under the employer-employee system that is the dominant form of production. If the goods aren’t sold, the work done to produce them might as well not have been done, for they will not be used. It is thus the network of exchanges against money that binds all forms of work together into an economic system. Money is central to modern society, a society based on the principle of individual ownership (even though the vast majority of people don’t own very much) because it represents the social character of productive activity in a form—bits of metal, paper symbols, or electronic pulses—possessable by individuals.

Like all forms of representation, money is an abstracting device: by being exchangeable for any kind of product, money transforms the different kinds of work that make these products into elements of an abstraction, “social productive activity.” The abstract character of modern production is not only an idea, but has social reality: for businesses, the particular product they sell is of interest only as a means to acquire money that, as a representation of social productive activity in general, can be exchanged for any sort of thing. Executives move capital from one area of business to another not because they care more about automobiles than soybeans or stuffed animals, but to make money. This is what “capital” is: money used to make money. A business that does not make a profit will cease to exist, so the ability to make money—to increase the quantity owned of the representation of social productive activity—constrains what goods are produced, or even whether money is invested in the production of goods at all.

The fact that money is the most important practical way in which the social aspect of productive activity is represented allows it to misrepresent social reality as well. By being exchanged for money, natural resources like land and oil deposits are represented in the same terms—as worth sums of money—as humanly produced things. Interest—more money—must be paid for the use of someone else’s money. Things that are simply symbols of money, like IOUs, including complicated IOUs like banknotes and stocks and bonds issued by companies, can be bought and sold, since they entitle their owners to money incomes and so can be treated as if they were saleable products. And since goods must be priced so that their sale allows businesses to make a profit, even in the case of actual products the amount something costs is affected by the amount people are able and willing to spend on it.

As a result, profit, as a portion of the sales price, misleadingly appears to be generated by the activities of particular firms, especially because it is appropriated by individual businesses, who compete with each other to get as much of it as possible. In reality, profit—because it exists in the abstract form of money, rather than in that of particular kinds of product—must be produced by the whole network of productive activities held together by the exchange of goods for money. It is with the goal of making money that employers buy equipment and materials from each other and labor from employees, who in turn buy back the portion of their product not used to replace or expand the productive apparatus and—let’s not forget—to provide the employers with their own, generally expensive, consumables. The capitalistically-desired output of this whole process, profit, is the money-representation of the labor performed beyond that required to reproduce the class of employees (paid in the form of wages) and to provide the goods required for production. It is the whole social system that produces profit, though individual companies get to keep it.

The social character of profit can be seen in the very fact that the level of profitability on capital investment alters over time, independently of the wishes of businessmen, who, like everyone else, must adapt to the price movements that determine how well they do (it is this that gives rise to the idea of “the economy” as a set of impersonal forces like the laws of nature.) Competition for profit forces businesses to charge similar prices for similar products; since they must themselves buy goods (labor and materials), their ability to compete by lowering prices depends on the production techniques they employ. In this way, the social character of the system asserts itself through pressure on individual firms to raise productivity, insofar as this leads to higher profits.

Historically, this has led to a strong tendency towards decreasing the labor force in comparison to the amount it produces (while, of course, increasing the number of workers absolutely as the system grew). Employers first made labor more productive by assembling workers into large workshops, within which their work was divided into smaller and smaller tasks. This led to the substitution of machines for people, whenever this raised profitability, and to the invention of the modern assembly line, whose speed enforced high levels of labor intensity. By the end of the twentieth century, most production had become mechanized mass production, requiring less and less labor relative to a growing quantity of machinery and, of course, raw materials.

This shift has obvious consequences for the profitability of capital. If profit is the money-representation of the labor performed by employees of all of society’s businesses in excess of the work required to replace raw materials, tools, and those employees themselves, then it will decline relative to total investment if businesses increasingly invest more of their money in machines and materials than in labor. Karl Marx, who first figured this out, called it “the most important law of modern political economy”: the tendency of the rate of profit to fall. Marx’s explanation of the tendency to declining profits, noticed well before him by nineteenth-century economists, is a controversial one, to say the least. But it led to a prediction that has proved all too correct: that the history of capitalism would take the form of a cycle of depressions and prosperities. And it explains the correlation Mitchell demonstrated between changes in profitability and the business cycle.

 Marx pointed out that the growth of capitalism, with its bias towards mechanization, led to an increase in the amount of money needed to continue to expand production, and so to the increasing size of individual companies. For the largest 100 firms in the United States, for instance, in real terms the amount of money invested in equipment per worker doubled between 1949 and 1962. And, of course, as increasing mechanization raised labor productivity, growing amounts of raw materials must be paid for. One consequence of this is that if the profitability of capital falls, at some point the amount of profit will be inadequate for further expansion of the system. (The General Motors factory in Lordstown, Ohio, then the most automated automobile factory in the world, cost $100 million to build in 1966; in 2002, GM spent $500 million to modernize the plant, which permitted reducing the workforce from 7000 to 2500. Only seven years later, GM is begging for a government handout to avoid going out of business.)

Slowing or stagnant investment means a shrinking market for produced goods. Employers neither invest capital in the purchase of buildings, machinery, and raw materials nor pay the wages which workers would have spent on consumer goods. A slowdown in investment, that is, is experienced by workers as a rise in unemployment and by businessmen as a contraction of markets. This is a self-magnifying process, as declining demand causes business failures, higher unemployment, and further contraction of demand. At the same time, since businessmen (and other borrowers) are increasingly unable to meet financial obligations, the various forms of IOUs issued by banks and brokerage houses become increasingly valueless, causing a financial crisis, while falling stock prices reflect the declining value of business enterprises. Individuals and institutions hoard money, rather than invest it. In short, capitalism finds itself in a depression.

But in a capitalist economy, what causes suffering for individuals can be good for the system. As firms go bankrupt and production goods of all sorts go unsold, the surviving companies can buy up buildings, machinery and raw materials at bargain prices, while land values fall. There is market pressure for the design of new, more efficient and cheaper machinery. As a result, the cost of capital investment declines. At the same time, rising unemployment drives down wages. Capitalists’ costs are thus lower while the labor they employ is more productive than before, as people are made to work harder and on newer equipment. The result is a revival in the rate of profit, which makes possible a new round of investment and therefore an expansion of markets for production goods and consumer goods alike. A depression, that is, is the cure for insufficient profits; it is what makes the next period of prosperity possible, even as that prosperity will in turn generate the conditions for a new depression.

Given this pattern, what is unusual about the current situation is not the decline of profits visible in the global economy in the late 1960s or the serious downturn of the early 1970s, but the fact that a real depression did not materialize until 2008. Like earlier crises, the Great Depression of the 1930s, together with the enormous destructive force of the Second World War, laid the foundations for the new prosperity that came to life in the postwar Golden Age (see www.brooklynrail.org/2008/11/express/risky-business). It was not surprising, in view of the history of the business cycle, that this new prosperity began to decline by the end of the 1960s. But if capitalism remained at base the same system, the economic policy practiced by governments had changed. On the one hand, the political dangers threatened by the mass social movements unleashed by the previous depression, as mass unemployment radicalized the population, were unacceptable to the governing elite of the capitalist states, especially in the context of what was believed to be an epic confrontation with Communism. On the other hand, it was also imagined that Keynesian methods of deficit financing could control the ravages of the business cycle. And in fact the continuously growing level of government spending on military and civilian projects after 1945, which increased the demand for goods and services beyond that produced by the capitalist economy proper, created prosperous conditions despite declining profitability.

In addition, the money that governments—the U.S. above all—printed to pay for all this spending, together with the credit private financial establishments were encouraged by central banks to extend to corporate and individual borrowers, made possible the debt expansion that underwrote individual consumption, corporate acquisitions and, especially from the 1980s on, ever more forms of speculation, in real estate, the stock market, and (with the refinement of derivatives) the ups and downs of speculation itself. This ever-increasing public, business, and individual debt appeared on bank and other business balance sheets as profits, despite their missing foundation in real productive enterprise.

Meanwhile, just as in earlier periods of economic decline, pressure was put on workers to work harder, while labor costs were lowered by moving plants from high wage to low wage areas or simply by using the threat of such moves to cut wages and benefits. Starting in the 1980s, spending on the socialized wage payments constituted by welfare-state programs was cut, freeing up money for corporate use. As it was supposed to, all this contributed to an actual increase in profits by lowering production costs, but evidently not by enough, given the costs of production goods, to make possible a new round of capital investment on a scale able to challenge the charms of speculation’s short-run high returns. The result was the economic situation which has arrived so shockingly during the last year, though for several decades the warning signs—debt crises, recessions, bank collapses, stock market failures—were clear enough. Generally ascribed to lax regulation, greed, or bad central-bank policy, the current economic collapse is in line with the whole history of capitalism as a system. What we are faced with today is, more or less, the depression that should have come much earlier, but which political-economic policy was able to delay—in part by displacing it to poor parts of the world, but largely by an historically unprecedented creation of debt in the rich parts—for thirty-odd years.

Now the crisis is here. What form will it take? And what can be done about it? I will turn to these questions in the next (and last) article in this series.

Josef K: "A Brief History of the Crisis"

posted Jan 23, 2009, 11:33 AM by John Clegg   [ updated Feb 4, 2009, 2:03 PM by franqui coat ]

A concise background to the current financial crisis and recession.

However it may seem, the current crisis didn’t come out of nowhere. Following WWII, the government and employers were keen to appease a population weary from years of war and rationing. The NHS was founded in 1948, and the opportunity for a reconstruction boom created the possibility of ‘productivity deals.’ These were agreements between employers and the unions for workers to implement productivity improvements in return for a share of the profits in the form of higher wages.

This settlement lasted up until the late 1960s, when two factors converged to derail it. Firstly, there was a growing wave of industrial unrest with strikes and other forms of action rippling out around the world. Many of these took the form of wildcat action outside of union control. Workers were fed up with years of producing more and more while their lives were still reduced to work, as all that extra productivity hadn’t led to shorter hours.

The second factor was the end of the post-war boom, which saw economic growth slow dramatically – making productivity deals unaffordable if profit levels were to be maintained. It also saw rising inflation eat away at the wage improvements over the last decade, adding fuel to the fire of workers' militancy. The struggles of this period were highly successful, with workers winning large concessions. However, this set the stage for a concerted counter-attack.

At the end of the 70s, Margaret Thatcher came to power in the UK on a mission to break the working class. Reagan soon followed in the US. Both of them isolated and took on workers sector by sector, doing deals with some unions while attacking others in a divide and rule strategy. The decisive defeats were the miners’ strike of 1984/5 in the UK, and Reagan’s attack on the air traffic controllers in the US in 1981. These are defeats from which we’ve yet to recover.

With workers broken, Thatcher and Reagan set about a series of reforms which set the scene for today’s crisis. Firstly, old centres of workers' militancy (mining, manufacturing) were systematically dismantled and outsourced to low-wage economies overseas. Whereas in the UK in 1971 over 70% of people were employed in primary industries (like mining) or manufacturing, today over 70% of workers are in the service sector. Secondly, the banking sector was massively deregulated, allowing the creation of all sorts of complicated ‘derivatives’ markets, which ultimately resulted in the credit crunch as it proved impossible to know what all these pieces of paper were really worth.

An effect of breaking workers' militancy was of course to keep wages down, and we’ve all got used to sub-inflation pay rises every year (in other words pay cuts). While this boosts profits, the problem with this is that it keeps consumer spending - and thus economic growth - down, since you can’t buy lots of things when you’re skint. Unless of course you get a credit card. So this problem was ‘solved’ by extending massive consumer credit, based mostly on rising house prices, to provide the spending power to purchase all those commodities coming out of the new manufacturing centres in the Far East and elsewhere.

Parallel to this, without primary industries or manufacturing the economy came to rely more and more on the banking and financial sector, with the ‘square mile’ of the City of London alone accounting for around 5% of the UK’s economy. This sector was also now heavily reliant on rising house prices, with complicated ‘mortgage derivatives’ being one of the major assets held by the big banks. Of course when the housing bubble burst, everything started to unravel. Household name banks teetered on the brink of collapse, as did the entire financial system. Credit dried up, and with it the economy swung into recession.

There is much talk comparing it to the collapse of 1929, except nobody knows how bad it’s going to get, and this time it’s global. Already there have been riots by workers laid off from thousands of factories in China, and food riots across the globe as food prices rise much faster than incomes. This then is the context for the coming ‘claw back’ attacks on our living standards that are set to try and make us pay for a crisis that was not of our making.

Written for the Tea Break bulletin in December 2008.


Cramer: "Invisible Hand” Ideology and “Underconsumption” Mythology

posted Nov 14, 2008, 1:46 PM by mllynn2@yahoo.com   [ updated Nov 16, 2008, 10:54 AM by John Clegg ]

“Invisible Hand” Ideology and “Underconsumption” Mythology

 

Testifying before Congress (10/24/08), former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan said we each have an ideology that guides us in understanding and interpreting what goes on in the world.  He said his ideology was “flawed.”  I don’t think so.  Greenspan’s ideology promotes a classical model of the market economy where each corporation operates in accordance with its self-interest in the competition to increase profits no matter what it takes, no matter who gets hurt.  The former Fed Chairman’s ideological forefather, Adam Smith, proclaimed in his seminal work of 1776, “Wealth of Nations,” each corporation endeavors to employ its capital so as to produce the greatest value.  It has no intention of promoting the public interest.  Each intends only his own security, his own gain.  Each is led by the “INVISIBLE HAND:” supply and demand in the self-regulating competitive free market.  (Smith’s capitalization; my paraphrasing of his pronouncement).  The reality is that this ideologically based model of the economic world is extremely limited and has no room for historically predictable, booms and busts, recessions and depressions in the domestic and global economy.

 

What is much more maddening is the mythology that sustains the free-market ideology, and which is so pervasive we take it in unconsciously as innocent toddlers and preach it unquestioningly as adults.  This mythology, broadcast several times a day by the mass media, particularly on NPR I notice, teaches us that what drives the economy is the demand of working people for consumer goods!

 

If this is truly a “consumer driven economy”, i.e., dependent on citizens’ demand for consumer goods, then why is the solution to every significant economic downturn found in layoffs, cutting workers’ wages, real income-reducing inflation, working longer hours for less pay, and “tightening our belts” (consuming less)?  And, why is it that those who are “bailed out” are enormous investment institutions and the largest manufacturing companies?  Why, asked a caller of an NPR program hostess, why doesn’t the government give the trillion dollar bailout money directly to the individuals who have lost their retirement 401Ks, or seen their stock portfolio drown in toxic debt, or to those who were seduced into believing they could refinance sub-prime mortgages and are now losing their homes.  Then, the caller continued, we could all go out and spend that money, increase consumer demand, and get the economy going again!  If our consumption is paramount, why did I get a “stimulus check” for $300, and Bank America got $250 Billion?  Collectively, taxpaying consumers supposedly got $100 Billion. The biggest financial institutions divvy up $1 Trillion and counting. 

 

On another NPR program the host of “On Point,” expressed alarm that so many “big box stores across the nation are closing down.  These big retail discount stores and supermarkets where workers purchase much of what they consume will not be getting a federal bailout.  Why not, if it is our demand that drives the economy?

If the consumption of working people is the driver of economic growth, why is it that during previous economic downturns, after cutting wages and introducing policies that drastically lower real income and consumption, the economy took off again and reached even higher rates of productivity and profitability than prior to the recession/depression.  If the object of our economic system is our—yours and my---consumption, then how is it that business and industry claim they consume 80% of all energy resources?  And, why do responsible ecologist point out that if all of us citizens of the U.S. went completely green (electric cars, solar heat, local organic produce, etc.), we would only eliminate 20 % of the greenhouse gases produced in the U.S. (note the same 20/80 split)?

If our personal consumption is the goal, why has big oil been closing down operations in the U.S. while exporting to European markets since the 1970’s?  Why, as Antonio Juhasz reports in her in-depth examination of the oil industry, are US oil companies  “stockpiling” and “hoarding” oil?  Economists Johnathan Nitzan and Shimshon Bichler, among others, have also pointed out that the UK and USA oil companies promoted the creation of the OPEC cartel precisely to do what would be illegal in their own countries:  restrict supply in order to raise prices.   Why, if it is our consumer demand that this economic system strives to satisfy?

 

The simple answer is that Capitalists do operate in their own self-interest in pursuit of profits in order to stay competitive, expand their production and increase their accumulated capital. That is the object of economic activity in our system of production and distribution. Capital accumulation is the goal; profitability the driver; wage-labor the sine qua non.  Most workers know this.  The bigger question is why does that system fail periodically; and fail on a grander and more global level each time?  Greenspan’s ideology cannot explain these repeated economic crises we experience periodically; and it does not allow for acknowledgement that they are endemic to our economic system.

Numerous investors and economists have noted that this financial crisis is just the tip-top of the iceberg.  That the problems with the underlying “real economy” have been going on for over thirty years.  They state that we have to get back to manufacturing real things, not betting on inflated financial paper with no material backing or real value. (Even Dennis Kucinich was heard to exclaim after passage of the bailout bill, “We are going backwards, from an industrial economy to a financial economy!”)  Having acknowledged the larger, underlying problem, all critics--- whether radical, progressive, leftist or conservative--- quickly return to gossiping about the sexy intrigues of bankers, hedge fund manages, and other irresponsible lenders accused of having built the financial house of cards.  It really does remind one of the drunk who insists on looking for his car keys under the street light, rather than were he lost them in the dark shadows.

 

But these critics cannot be blamed for avoiding a discussion of  problems for which they have no explanation, any more than Greenspan can be blamed for the limitations of his ideology.   There never has been, in accepted economic theory, a valid explanation of why historically worsening “business cycles” occur routinely in our system of production. Nor is there an answer to why, after each “bust” and cut in wages and consumption, the next “boom” takes off at an even higher rate of growth than before the down cycle.  That is why spreading the mythology of the all-powerful consumer is crucial. The consumer, imperial driver of the system, is always to blame for problems with the underlying “real economy:” either we consume too much, or not enough; or save too much, or not enough.  Economist Wesley Clair Mitchell subjected the “economic crisis theories” based on shortage of consumer demand to thorough statistical tests of the historical data.  He concluded that the theory that depressions were caused by lack of consumer demand did not hold up; and that depressions in our economic system are not deviations from normality.   He found that each major slow down in the economy began with a fall in the price of “producers’ goods,”--- a drop in demand for industrial plant, material and machinery---not in consumer goods. The same is true today. A perusal of the Wall Street Journal for the past thirty years will reveal many articles confirming that a cut in demand for production of industrial manufacturer’s goods precedes lay-offs and the subsequent drop in “consumer demand.” 

 

John Maynard Keynes, the revered godfather of liberal economics, much loved for his theory that government can supply the necessary demand to overcome depressions, is often resurrected in times of economic crises. In the 1930s, he even envisioned a stage of capital “abundance” so great that government intervention would no longer be necessary, and consumption would become the sole objective of economic production.  That was a dream for the way-off future, for Keynes knew, as does every economist and corporate CEO, that our economic system depends on capital accumulation in its real material form, which includes industrial infrastructure, transport and technology systems, factory equipment, machinery, enormous manufacturing and administrative fortifications, and manufacturing materials (things you and I could never consume personally). The words of General Motors Chairman Gernstenberg, back in the 1970’s, reflect the ideological beliefs of Greenspan and the economics profession then and now: “Not one of our grand national goals---not one---can be accomplished unless business prospers.  Profits from which come all wages, taxes, and dividends, fuel the growth of our nation, and future depends on the profitability of free enterprise.” 

 

Today’s economic apologists convince us that the system of  “toxic assets,” “credit-default swaps,” “naked short trading,” bundled securities,” “derivatives,” “Ninja loans,” “illiquid assets,” and all the many other fabricated financial "products" are much too complicated for us to understand.  They insist that what is good for Wall Street is good for Main Street . Yet they have little to say about the real crisis in economic production that preceded and underlies all the financial frenzy.

 

As the industrial economy began slowing in the 1970s, economists started referring to non-manufacturing corporations as “industries:” the “financial industry,” the "banking industry,” “the insurance industry,” etc.  Later, they turned to the field of psychology for concepts and terminology: “Consumer confidence,” “market preferences,”  “stock market sensitivities,” or “sentiments of financial traders” became the focus. A new economic vocabulary can not cover up the facts on the ground: Over the past several decades, the industrial economy has become increasingly troubled as government interventions, monetary and financial manipulations have failed to overcome the underlying, real economic crisis. The belief now is that the $1 Trillion injection of taxpayers’ money into the financial sector will jump-start the real manufacturing economy that has been struggling since the early 1970s. So far, the banks have refused to loan this money because, they say, there are no profitable industrial projects to invest in.

Economic theory has had little influence on government attempts to prop up a failing economic system. During the Great Depression, President Roosevelt commented that he had to invoke policies very similar to those used in Communist Russia and Nazi Germany.  FDR claimed not to have understood a thing Keynes tried to explain to him about how the economy works.  It took World War II and government direction of production for military purposes to get us out of the Great Depression—not economic theory.

 

Today we are nearing the end of the old ideological road. Our political and economic system is undergoing radical change.  The ideological “autobahn” under construction is being built for us by a government representing the needs of the largest industrial corporations and financial institutions.  We can continue to suffer the consequences of letting them chart the way of change, or we can plan a new path forward, grounded in everyday material reality and values, designed to benefit the entire people. Seeing through the myths of “consumerism,” and the ideology of “this most perfect of all economic systems” is a necessary first step.

 

Mary Lynn Cramer has dedicated twenty-five years to low paying "applied economics," working as a bilingual social worker with families and children. She has degrees in economic history, economic theory and social work. She can be reached at mllynn2@yahoo.com. This is a revised copy of the original article which appeared in Counterpunch, 10/27/08 entitled “Greenspan’s Higher Power.”

 

A House of Cards, from fantasy finance to global crash

posted Nov 12, 2008, 12:04 PM by John Clegg

A House of Cards from fantasy finance to global crash by Gerry Gold & Paul Feldman

An 82 page pamphlet that succinctly introduces many of the Marxian concepts employed on this site, as well as the historical background to the current crisis (although it was written a year ago and thus lacks an account of the collapse itself).

Ramaa Vasudevan - Financialization: A Primer

posted Nov 9, 2008, 6:52 AM by David Calnitsky   [ updated Sep 14, 2009, 10:10 AM by John Clegg ]

Mary Lynn Cramer: "Their Assets, Our Debts" and "Economic Amnesia"

posted Oct 29, 2008, 7:08 AM by John Clegg

Two clearly written articles by Mary Lynn Cramer giving an historical background to the crisis as well as explaining the limits of mainstream economic interpretations of it.

"Their Assets, Our Debts"
CounterPunch, Sept. 27-28 2008

"Economic Amnesia" Weekend Local, Oct. 9 2008

Richard Wolff: "Capitalist Crisis, Marx's Shadow"

posted Oct 9, 2008, 8:00 AM by John Clegg   [ updated Nov 12, 2008, 4:44 PM ]

Richard Wolff: "Capitalist Crisis, Marx's Shadow".
A good clear introduction to the crisis. Argues that it is a delayed result of a 1970s underconsumptionist crisis. 
See also the video lecture: 
Capitalism Hits the Fan: A Marxian View 

Amehurst economists on the Market Meltdown

posted Oct 8, 2008, 6:33 PM by John Clegg   [ updated Oct 15, 2008, 8:18 PM ]

text and videos from UMass Amehurst Econ professors, explaining the crisis in very basic terms: Market Meltdown 101

Paul Mattick Jnr: "Up in Smoke" and "Risky Business"

posted Oct 8, 2008, 5:30 PM by John Clegg   [ updated Nov 11, 2008, 2:15 PM ]

A series of articles for the Brooklyn Rail introducing the crisis for lay readers.

part 1 "Up in Smoke"

part 2 "Risky Business"

1-10 of 10