Home

Note: The Official Version of this report has now been posted by the Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations.

Family Farms of North America

John Ikerd[i]

Family Farms Held in High Esteem

Historically, family farms held positions of respect and high esteem in the dominant cultures of North America and in much of the rest of the world. The first family farmers in North America were the indigenous peoples who had lived on the continent for centuries before the arrival of Europeans. Most depended primarily on hunting and gathering, but farming was common among many of the tribes of North America. These indigenous family farmers, like the early family farmers of Europe, usually included extended families. The families agreed on informal divisions of labor and divided the resulting production among kin groups within larger communities that farmed particular areas.[1] An extended family might tend a specific land area, giving it some sense of ownership or rights, however, there was no real sense of private property. Most farming areas were considered “common property” where all families could graze animals or farm cooperatively.

The indigenous farmers in what is now the United States (US) and Canada were displaced by immigrants from Europe. Among the early European settlers, farmers held positions of distinction in their communities. The very survival of these early agrarian societies depended on the ability of farmers to produce enough food to meet the needs of all. Unlike Europe, there were no landlord classes with large estates or landholdings in the US or Canada. The plantation agriculture of the US South prior to the 1860s Civil War was the exception rather than the rule. Family farming became rooted deeply in the cultures of both countries. The status of family farming in early Mexico was quite different. Indigenous Mexican farmers became unwilling workers, many virtual slaves, on large Spanish landholdings that were patterned after European feudal estates. Perhaps as a consequence, family farming in much of Mexico today still resembles the extended family, common property patterns of indigenous North America.

Thomas Jefferson, the third president of the United States, believed strongly that the “yeoman farmer” best exemplified the kind of “independence and virtue” that should be respected and supported by governments. He did not believe financiers, bankers, or industrialists could be trusted to be caretakers of democracy and therefore should not be encouraged. Adam Smith, an icon of capitalism and author of the classic, The Wealth of Nations, influenced the early development of both the United States and Canada. He observed that farmers ranked among the highest social classes in China and India, and suggested it would be the same everywhere if the “corporate spirit” did not prevent it. Smith never trusted businessmen to serve interests other than their own and held a particular distrust of corporations.

Smith’s reference to China was to the ancient philosophy of Confucius which ranks farmers second only to the academics or scholars in the Chinese social order. Following the farmer is the worker, and lastly, the businessman. Smith also suggested that “they who feed, clothe, and lodge the whole body of people, should have a share of the produce of their own labor as to themselves be tolerably well fed, clothed, and lodged.”[2] All of these respected historical figures placed those engaged in agriculture, who were family farmers, at or near the top of society and those concerned primarily with matters of economics and business at the lowest levels of society.

The Family Farm – Defined

Lack of Consensus. Over the centuries, families obviously have continued to farm, but no generally accepted definition of the “family farm” has emerged, in North America or elsewhere. Some of the commonly used statistical indicators of family farms were outlined in a 2014 “Dialogue of Family Farming in North America report:”[3] 1) source of the labor on the farm: whether provided by the family, paid employees, or some combination of the two; 2) source of capital: whether provided by the nuclear family, extended family, or non-farm investors; 3) primary decision maker: whether independent operator, user of licensed technologies, or contract producer of crops or livestock; 4) land tenure status of the operator: whether resident owner-operator, multi-year share-leaser, multi-year cash leaser, or renter from farm resident or non-resident landlord; 5) legal ownership of the farms: whether single proprietorship, partnership, family corporation, or publicly-traded corporation; 6) primary destination of production; whether for family use, local or regional market, international niche market, domestic commodity market, or international commodity market.

The likelihood of a farm being a true “family farm” decreases along these statistical gradients: from family labor to paid employees, family capital to non-farm investments, independent operator to contract producer, land owner to cash renter, single proprietor to corporation, and producing for families and local markets to producing for international markets. As relationships between the family and farm become less personal, the sense of interconnectedness of the family and farm decreases. The most commonly used criteria are probably the proportion of permanent labor provided by the farm family, the ability of the farmer to make day-to-day management decisions, and whether the farmer is a resident owner-operator or rents from a non-resident landlord. The family that provides the labor for a farm, makes the farm management decisions, and owns and lives on the farm is more likely to feel a deep, personal sense of connectedness to the farm, which characterizes true family farms. At some point along the continuums, the farm becomes a farm business rather than a family farm.

True family farmers have a strong “sense of place.” Ultimately, the interconnectedness of the family with the farm is what makes a farm a “family farm” and a family a “farm family.” On a true family farm, the farm and the family are inseparable. The same farm with a different family would be a different farm, and the same family with a different farm would be a different family. The landscape, the local climate, the community – “the feel of the farm” – become engrained in the family culture. The family and the land are inseparable parts of the same whole; the family farm is an emergent property of that whole. The family farm and the farm family both have characteristics that emerge when the family connects with the farm and no longer exist if the family leaves the farm. That’s why families cling to farms that have been in their families for decades. Some have even committed suicide when they were forced to leave their farms.

Family farmers also have a strong “sense of family.” Family farms can be good places to raise children and to sustain family relationships – both within and among generations. Farm family members who work together obviously have an opportunity to spend more quality time together than do most other modern families. Working, child rearing, recreation, and family life all happen at the same time and place – on the farm. Children who contribute to the chores on family farms grow up knowing they are valuable and valued as productive participants in the work and life of the family. Feeling valued gives them a better chance to develop a healthy sense of self-esteem or self-worth. Family farms survive and thrive by creating and sustaining the kind of positive, caring, personal relationships that are essential aspects of strong families.

Family farmers also have a strong “sense of community.” The farm is a reflection of the social and ethical values of the farm family in the community and the community often forms its opinions of the family in relation to their farm. If the farm is operated in ways that are either respectful or disrespectful of others in the community, the family is accordingly considered to be either responsible or irresponsible members of the community. Farm families often identify themselves, are identified by others, and identify others, in terms of networks of familial, social, and economic relationships within communities. More than 50 years of social science research has validated that US communities characterized by small to mid-size family farms tend to be better places to live, both economically and socially, than are communities dominated by large farming enterprises.[4]

Obviously, all family farms do not have all of the positive characteristics associated with sense of place, family, and community. But they have the potential to do so. It’s the positive “potentials” of family farms, not their past or present reality, that make them important to the families who choose this way of life, to their communities, to the sustainability of agriculture and the future of humanity.

Multifunctionality. With respect to the future, the most important descriptors of family farms relate to their multifunctionality, because multifunctionality is essential for sustainability. Sustainability may well be the defining question of the 21st century, and nowhere is sustainability more important than in agriculture. Sustainability is the ability to meet the needs of the present without diminishing opportunities for the future – paraphrasing the United Nation’s Bruntland Commission’s definition of “sustainable development.”[5] A civilization that cannot feed itself, in the present or future, obviously is not sustainable. A sustainable agriculture must be able to meet the needs of the present while maintaining the ecological and social integrity of the natural and human resources upon which its long-term productivity ultimately depends. Societies that cannot meet their needs through purely personal relationships must rely on impersonal economies that extend beyond their realm of personal relationships. Thus, a sustainable agriculture must be ecologically sound, socially responsible, and economically viable: it must be multifunctional.

Farms are inherently multifunctional in that they have inherent economic, ecological, and social consequences. Sustainable family farms are special in that they are intentionally multifunctional. They are managed to provide multiple benefits. Multifunctional family farms are not simply a means of economic livelihood for the family; they also are a social and ethical way of family life. They provide social and economic benefits to their communities and societies as well as to their families. They provide ecological benefits to communities, societies, and humanity though ethical stewardship of the land, water, air, and energy of the earth. Family owned and operated farms that are managed solely or predominately for economic benefits of the family are managed as mono-functional family farms, even though they have inevitable multiple effects on communities and ecosystems. Such farms are not sustainable. The family farms idealized by Jefferson, Smith, and others as being uniquely worthy of high esteem were multifunctional family farms.

Evolution of Family Farming in North America.

Enclosure of the Commons. The evolution of family farming in North America has been a continuation of trends begun in Europe in the 16th century. In his classic book, The Great Transformation, economist Karl Polanyi explains the historical consequences of “enclosing the commons,” or privatizing farmland, as a means of “commodifying” or giving economic value to land and labor.[6] Prior to the enclosure movement, European families had free access to farmland. As in indigenous North America, extended families may have felt some sense of “use rights” to the particular parcels of land they had tended over time, but there was no formal ownership of land as “private property.” Everyone had an equal right to use land in the commons to meet their basic needs for survival and sustenance. Uses of land for other purposes were determined by community consensus, not by markets.

Prior to the enclosures, market transactions had been limited primarily to international trade. The primary means of meeting basic physical or material needs were through subsistence farming and local gifting economies. Barter was generally limited to trade among people who didn’t have ongoing personal relationships. However, international markets had proven very effective in increasing the aggregate wealth of nations, as suggested by Adam Smith and other early capitalists. Markets had allowed individual countries to capitalize on their economic “comparative advantages.” Enclosing the commons would also allow individuals and villages to capitalize on their comparative economic advantages by responding to market incentives. This was consistent with prevailing economic thinking in Europe at the time and persists still today.

To allow markets to determine land use, farmland had to be privatized or commodified so it could be bought and sold and thus reallocated among buyers and sellers to ensure its highest economic use. The use of various parcels of land could then be determined by market competition rather than community consensus. The commodification of land, or allowing markets to establish the value to land, essentially forced the commodification of labor as well. Those who lost access to land and the ability to grow their own food were forced to sell their labor to employers, not only to thrive economically but to survive physically. This fundamentally changed the nature of family farms, farming in general, and ultimately the history of humanity.

People are inherently unequal in their ability to earn money in market economies. Each person has a different set of physical and mental capacities, aptitudes and opportunities, and initial endowments of financial and physical resources. However, all people have the same basic needs for food, clothing, shelter, and other necessities of life. The enclosures of farmland left many people without the ability to earn enough money to buy food for their families. Nonetheless, enclosures of the commons spread across Europe. “The years between 1760 and 1820 [were] the years of wholesale enclosure in which, in village after village, common rights are lost."[7] For the first time, able-bodied workers were left poor and hungry in communities where their neighbors were wealthy and well-fed. The enclosures in Europe, and the resulting poverty and hunger, were a significant factor in the mass migrations of Europeans who settled initially in the eastern regions of North America.

European migration. Farm families that migrated from Europe to the US and Canada, with the backing of their governments, carried out their own form of enclosure by forcing the indigenous people off their land, privatizing farmlands on the frontier, and eventually resettling the Native Americans on reservations.[8] The farmland typically was divided into parcels that a single family could manage with the technologies of the times. These early European family farmers generally relied heavily on family labor. The land had not been farmed intensively, and thus the soils in most areas were still fertile and productive. Since these early family farmers produced food primarily for their own families and local communities, they had little incentive to increase productivity beyond the land’s natural capacity.

The westward expansion of European settlements in North America was marked by major political events such as the Louisiana Purchase of 1803, which included much of what is now US territory west of the Mississippi River, and the US-Mexican War, which followed the annexation of Texas in 1845. The economic roots of industrial agriculture in the US can be seen in the westward migration which followed, particularly during the 1860s. Prior to this time, farming was the predominant way of life in America and most farms were clearly family farms. In 1860, farm families made up close to 50 percent of the US population and farmers were nearly 60 percent of the workforce.[9] When President Abraham Lincoln established the US Department of Agriculture in 1862, he called it the “people’s department.” Like Thomas Jefferson before him, he was reaffirming the “yeoman farmer” as the foundation of a democratic society.

Farm sizes had begun to increase by the mid-1800s, as farms on the US and Canadian prairies began to mechanize and expand production to provide food for growing populations in the East. Improved storage and transportation also meant that the grain surpluses could be traded abroad. Trade was particularly important in Canada, as agriculture became part of its staples economy supplying the “mother country” – England. This expansion of production and trade was the germination of agricultural industrialization, which is generally associated with the post-World War II era. The industrialization of agriculture probably ranks second in historical importance only to the initial domestication of plants and animals.[10] The industrial revolution in agriculture eventually transformed millions of North American farms from multifunctional ways of life into mono-functional farm businesses.

From family farms to farm businesses. The US Homestead Act of 1862, opened new land for farming in the Great Plains, enclosing lands that had continued to be occupied by Native Americans until then. Homesteads were initially limited to 160 acres, which was considered enough to sustain a family. In the early 1900s, homesteads were expanded to 320 acres for dry land farming and to 640 acres for livestock production. The intent at the time was not necessarily to expand agricultural production but instead to expand control over the continent through occupation. However, much of the homesteaded land eventually fell into the hands of large landowners and land speculators. With completion of the transcontinental railroad in 1869, the midlands of the US were opened for business, including agribusiness. Between 1870 and1890, the number of farms in the US grew by 80 percent, to 4.5 million.[11]

The Canadian government sold land on its western prairies for $10CAN per acre instead of offering it for homesteading. As in the US, a quarter-section or 160 acres was considered the basic farm settlement unit.[12] The Canadian prairies failed to draw many land buyers until 1900, more than a decade after completion of the transcontinental railway in 1885. Overproduction of agricultural commodities coupled with the economic “Panic of 1893” led to a collapse in export markets and widespread farm bankruptcies. The economic depression continued through the 1890s, halting the expansion of farming in the US as well as Canada. By 1900, only two million more hectares on the Canadian Prairies had been cleared and plowed. Between 1881 and 1901, the number of Canadian farms only grew from 10,000 to just over 55,000.

The historic economic “high-water mark” for US and Canadian agriculture came in the period between 1909 and 1918. Agricultural commodity prices were buoyed by strong export demand and the booming US and Canadian economies during the buildup to World War I.[13] Prices of agricultural commodities rose to levels that have not since been equaled in terms of “parity” or buying power of farm commodity sales. Between 1901 and 1921, 200,000 new farmers settled on the Canadian prairies, and by 1921, 16 million hectares of prairie lands were brought under cultivation. US farm numbers peaked at nearly 6.5 million in 1920, and Canadian farms totaled over 700 thousand in 1921. [14],[15] The average US farm size in 1920 was still only 140 acres. Average farm size in Canada in 1921 was somewhat larger at 198 acres per farm.

Farmer cooperatives played a significant role in the evolution of farming in Canada and in the northern tier of states in the US. Farmers in the Canadian Prairies and the US Great Plains were dependent on corporate grain merchants and the railroads to get their grain to eastern markets. They were dependent also on bankers, implement manufacturers, and local merchants to provide them with credit and other means of industrial production. To protect themselves from exploitation, they joined together in various cooperative organizations to gain bargaining power and provide their own services and means of production. New institutions, such as the United Farmers of Alberta, were “openly organized to protest the power of railroads, bankers, and grain merchants.”[16]

Grain growers were the first to make large-scale cooperatives work in North America. They were guided by the Rochdale principles of cooperation pioneered earlier in Europe, including democratic control, education and information, and concern for communities. [17] They addressed “both the economic and social problems farmers and farm families faced.”[18] Cooperatives were not limited to grain but also included dairy, fisheries, and a variety of other commodities. Service and bargaining cooperatives met the needs of farmers and retail food cooperatives met needs of consumers. Over time, government programs took over some of the functions of early cooperatives, and other cooperatives eventually evolved into mono-functional economic corporations. Nonetheless, cooperatives were a significant aspect of the evolution of family farming in North America and may have an even more important role to play in the future.

Continued mechanization and persistently profitable prices led to surplus agricultural production at a time when the global economy was falling into the post-war economic recession of 1920-21. This signaled the beginning of two decades of depressed agricultural commodity prices and farm incomes. The Dustbowl of the Great Plains and the consequent western agricultural migration are parts of the sad legacy of this era. Farm numbers remained stable in both countries during the Great Depression of the 1930s. It took the wartime economy of the 1940s to return US and Canadian farmers to positions of economic respectability. However, farming in North America has never regained its lofty economic status of the early 1900s.

Agricultural consolidation. Following World War II, millions of US and Canadian farms were destined to become farm businesses and agriculture was soon on its way to becoming an industry. Wartime technologies developed to produce munitions, poison gas, and tanks were soon adapted to produce chemical fertilizers, pesticides, and farm equipment. During the 1950s and 1960s, capital and technology replaced labor and management, and farms were consolidated into larger and fewer farm businesses. By 1970, farm numbers in the US had dropped by more than one-half from their peak, leaving only 2.8 million farms.[19] The surviving farms averaged 390 acres, nearly three times as large as in the 1920s. The number of Canadian farms peaked at 732 thousand in 1941 but dropped by one-half to 366 thousand by 1971. Canadian farm size nearly doubled during this period from 237 acres to 463 acres.[20]

North American agriculture was ripe for the economic euphoria that arose from expanding export markets during the 1970s. On the advice of then US Secretary of Agriculture Earl Butz, farmers planted fencerow-to-fencerow and then tore out the fencerows, windbreaks, and anything else that stood in the way of industrial farming. North American farmers were going to provide food for the booming global economy, and there seemed to be no limit to continuing agricultural prosperity. However, the agricultural experts failed to anticipate the global economic recession of the 1980s, which dried up export markets and caused commodity prices to plunge. Farmers were caught with large debts at record-high interest rates with prices too low to cover their financial commitments. American agriculture was confronted with the “farm financial crisis of the 1980s,” as it is stilled called among those who remember the devastation of rural America that occurred during that time.

Roughly one-fourth of the remaining farms in the US went out of business during that decade. Farm numbers fell to around two million and have since remained at that general level. The decline in farm numbers during the 1980s in Canada was less dramatic than in the US, but Canadian farm numbers continued to decline to 205 thousand in 2011. The average farm size in the US is now 421 acres and Canadian farms average 778 acres, with large farms and ranches on the Canadian Prairies accounting for much of the difference.

The agricultural transformation has been even more profound than indicated by the drop in farm numbers and increase in farm size. The survivors were mostly in two groups: smaller family farms on which farming had remained a way of life and larger specialized farm businesses that had prospered during the 1970s. Those who suffered most were on mid-sized, full-time family farms. The trend toward fewer traditional mid-sized family farms has continued in the US and Canada, as some continue to transition into larger commercial farming operations and others are replaced by smaller part-time farms, including those producing for niche markets.[21] Control of total agricultural production in both countries has become consolidated among a relatively small number of large, industrial farming operations.

From land reform to reconsolidation – Mexico. Farming in Mexico has followed a path quite different from the US and Canada, but the tendency toward industrial consolidation has been much the same. [22] In 1876, Porfirio Díaz of Spain established a dictatorship in Mexico that lasted until 1911. He emphasized modernisation of the whole country, which included enclosing and privatizing farmland. As in the US and Canada, railroads were built to encourage expansion of agricultural production beyond the needs of local markets. Diaz established banks and promoted foreign investments to encourage industrialization. His is farm policies, similar to those of the US and Canada, focused on increasing large, landed estates to the detriment of communal lands and small farms. These large estates (haciendas) were intended to minimize food costs in the domestic urban market and to provide agricultural products for export.

The main beneficiaries of industrial agriculture in Mexico have been an agrarian oligarchy, the military elite, and foreign corporations that have invested in Mexican agriculture. The resulting social inequity, deprivation of access to farmland, and the exploitation of peasants and workers has led to repeated rebellions and social struggles.[23] These conditions spawned the Mexican revolution of 1910, leading to a new Constitution in 1917. The new constitution was established on the principles of national sovereignty with respect to natural resources, agrarian land reform, labor rights, and education that is free, obligatory, and secular. These principles were implemented primarily during the government of Cárdenas. He redistributed some 18 million hectares of land between 1934 and 1940, twice as much as his predecessors combined. By 1940 most of the country's arable land had been redistributed to peasant farmers, and approximately one-third of all Mexicans had benefited from the agrarian reform program.

The new constitution established three different forms of land tenure in Mexico: private, public, and social. Social property was further subdivided into communal land in Southern Mexico and ejido lands elsewhere, which are held in common and farmed cooperatively or individually.[24] The ejido, or communal land holdings, constitute the primary form of land tenure in Mexico. Private lands were worked by owners, sharecroppers, and landless peasants; social lands were worked by colonos (settlers) or members of ejidos, known as ejidatarios. The constitution held private ownership of land to be a privilege rather than an absolute right, and it allowed the state to expropriate lands that it judged not to serve a useful social purpose. Between 1924 and 1984, the government expropriated and redistributed more than 77 million hectares of large-estate land, amounting to more than one-third of the national territory.

Agrarian reform obviously increased the proportion of Mexico's arable land held by minifundistas or smallholders. The share of total crop land held by large estates fell from 70 percent in 1923 to 29 percent by 1960, while that held by small farms of fewer than five hectares rose from seven percent in 1930 to more than 33 percent by the 1980s. In an attempt to increase the economic efficiency and productivity of small farms, the Mexican government welcomed the international agencies that promoted the Green Revolution. They promoted the use of improved varieties, fertilizers, insecticides, herbicides, agricultural machinery and irrigation. After its apparent initial success, the Green Revolution lost favor in the 1970s, as Mexico’s deficit commercial trade balance and the external debt increased 400 percent and 275 percent, respectively between 1971 and 1975.

Declining agricultural production and mounting food imports gave Mexican President Salinas, who was elected in 1988, political momentum to reform the land tenure system. In 1991, he announced a constitutional reform of the ejido, of which 58 percent contained five hectares or less. A subsequent reform of land tenure rules in February 1992 gave Mexico's three million ejidatarios formal title to their land, enabling them to lease or sell their plots if a majority of members of their ejido agreed. No further land would be distributed, and joint ventures with private capital were legalized and encouraged. These reforms were intended to reverse the trend toward smaller farming units and to stimulate rural investment by allowing ejidatarios to use their holdings as collateral for raising capital. These actions set the stage for the North American Free Trade agreement of 1994 (NAFTA) between Mexico, the US, and Canada.

The economic globalization of North American agriculture which began in the 1980s culminated with the NAFTA in 1994, which opened Mexican markets to unrestricted imports from the US and Canada. Mexican markets were soon flooded with subsidized US corn. The result was a strong polarization of economic opportunities and incomes between large industrial farming operations in northern Mexico and the largely subsistence family farmers elsewhere. Although the Mexican constitution limited private holdings to 100 hectares, by the early 1990s Mexico had more than 40,000 farms of 101 hectares or larger and some 500 farms larger than 50,000 hectares. The earlier movement away from industrial agriculture in Mexico has clearly been reversed. As in the US and Canada, family farms in Mexico are being consolidated into large farm business in an attempt to increase competitiveness in the global economy.

Challenges to Family Farms

Abandonment by government farm programs. North American farm families today face a number of major challenges – some are continuing while others are new. Perhaps the most important challenges in all three countries are government farm policies that increasingly support the industrialization of farming in a quest for ever-greater economic efficiency. This has been a continuing challenge in the US and Canada and has intensified in all three countries with the inclusion of Mexico in the NAFTA agreement of 1994. The increasing emphasis of farm policies on economic efficiency makes it even more difficult for multifunctional family farms to survive economically while maintaining their commitments to societal and ecological multifunctionality.

The only logical justification for government policies unique to agriculture and farming is to ensure food security. Trade policies are common to all sectors of economies. Food security in the US has traditionally been defined as access to adequate quantities of wholesome foods to support healthy active lifestyles, although the terminology has changed over time. As people around the world have learned, or are learning, market economies simply will not ensure food security, and thus, virtually every nation has some form of farm policy. Markets only provide enough food for those who have enough money to buy enough food. Food security requires that all have enough food, regardless of whether they have enough money. Food security is a necessary condition for agricultural sustainability, but food security alone is not sufficient. Food security is about meeting the needs of all in the present while agricultural sustainability extends the mandate for food security to those of future generations as well as those of the present.

The historic strategy for food security in the US was to keep enough farm families on the land, farmers who were committed to caring for the land, to produce enough food for everyone in the nation. Government farm programs in the US were established during the Great Depression of the 1920s and 1930s – while the US was still an agrarian nation. These early farm programs were but one aspect of the so-called New Deal of the 1930s, instituted by President Franklin Roosevelt. The New Deal included a wide range of government programs to address growing economic and social inequities. Government subsidies for farm families at that time provided badly needed income to people in rural areas, helping to preserve a way of life for farm families as well as provide both economic and food security for the nation.

Industrial agricultural policies. The changes in American agriculture following World War II led to fundamental changes in US farm policies. Farms powered by horses and solar energy gave way to farms powered by tractors and fossil energy. Cheap nitrogen fertilizers and pesticides encouraged farmers to abandon crop rotations and diversified crop and livestock farming as the means of managing pests and maintaining soil fertility. Farms were being transformed into factories without roofs and fields and feedlots into biological assembly lines.

The focus of US farm policy shifted from preserving family farms to promoting agricultural productivity, particularly during the 1960s and early1970s. A more efficient agriculture would lead to lower food prices, making adequate quantities of wholesome and nutritious food affordable for everyone. The logical farm policies for achieving this objective were designed to facilitate and promote the industrialization of agriculture. The Land Grant University system in the US, created by various Acts of Congress between 1862 and 1914, responded by shifting from its pre-war focus on empowering farm families with education and information to developing and promoting industrial agricultural technologies.

Many people associate industrialization with the transition from an agrarian to manufacturing economy. However, industrialization is more accurately defined as a mental model or paradigm for organizing and managing resources – land, labor, and capital. The rural to urban migration of the 1900s was not the essence but simply a consequence of economic industrialization. The fundamental strategies of industrial organizations are specialization, standardization, and consolidation of control. Specialization facilitates division of labor – allowing each person to do fewer things better. Specialized functions then must be standardized so that each contributes its part to a coherent whole. The standardized functions can then be simplified and routinized, allowing control to be consolidated into larger, more efficient production units. In competitive market economies, profits provide the motivation for industrialization.

Specialization in farming led to mechanization and simplification of production processes, allowing farms to become larger and thereby achieve the “economies of scale” associated with industrial production. Industrial farming allowed fewer specialized farmers to produce the nation’s food supply, thus freeing others to specialize in manufacturing the other activities associated with modern, industrial society. The transition from small family farms to large commercial farming enterprises was generally accepted as a logical consequence of government farm policy, even if not an explicit objective. Larger farms and fewer farms would make the nation both more food secure and economically secure. Farmers still made up more than a quarter of the US workforce during the 1960s, and a more efficient agriculture would free more ‘unneeded’ farmers to work in the factories and offices of the growing industrial economy.

Every major farm program in the US since the New Deal era, in one way or another, has facilitated, supported, or promoted agricultural industrialization – thereby promoting consolidation of agricultural production into fewer and larger economic production units. For example, price supports, deficiency payments, crop insurance, and disaster payments, all reduce the risks associated with specializing in producing one or a few basic commodities. Without such programs, a diversity of crops and livestock enterprises would be essential to manage production and market risks, which would also help maintain the ecological health and natural productivity of the soil. Grades and standards facilitate standardization and routinization of production for mass markets. Subsidized credit, investment tax credits, and accelerated depreciation of buildings and equipment encourage mechanization and consolidation into larger production units. US farmers are told they should either “get big or get out” of farming.

However, there is growing public skepticism regarding farm policies in the US, fueled by large government payments to larger farms and wealthy landowners. More than 60 percent of US farmers receive no government subsidies, while the top ten percent of subsidy recipients receive 75 percent of total payments.[25] The recent shift in funding from direct payments to crop insurance subsidies will not change this situation. There seems to be no limit to the ability of those formulating US farm policy to find ways to continue promoting the mono-functional, industrial paradigm of agriculture.

Globalization of agricultural policies. As US agricultural production continued to expand well beyond needs for domestic consumption, the focus of farm policy shifted from production for domestic consumption to producing for export markets. US agriculture would continue to ensure domestic food security by maintaining an agricultural trade surplus in global markets. US farm policy then became closely linked with US trade policy. The official US position on agricultural trade has been to push for “free markets” – through the General Agreement on Tariff and Trade (GATT), the World Trade Organization (WTO), the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), and other bilateral and regional trade agreements.

Over time, the US and Canadian agricultural economies have grown to become dominant players in a global industrial agro-food system. The US is the major agricultural exporter in the world and Canada ranks fifth among nations. Approximately 50 percent of the farm value of Canadian agricultural production is exported and exports account for about 30 percent of US net farm income. While the US is clearly the dominant player in the global food arena, Canadian agriculture has been and remains closely interconnected with US agriculture and with that of the larger global industrial agro-food system.[26]

US farmers continue to be told that they have a moral obligation to expand production to help “feed the world,” and that growing global food demand will challenge their ability to do so in the future. However, the US biofuels mandate[27] of 2005 has caused many to seriously question the proclaimed commitment of US agriculture to providing food for the world’s poor and hungry people. The mandate specifies percentages of US fuels to be derived from renewable sources by particular dates. Meeting the mandates has resulted in 40 percent of the US corn crop in recent years being devoted to ethanol production.[28] This has only served to accentuate the emphasis of farm policy on productivity and economic efficiency, magnifying its attendant negative impacts.

Farm policies in Canada are similar in many respects to those of the US but are even more dominated by international trade considerations. The inclusion of agriculture in the GATT was welcomed by Canada as well as the US and the multinational agribusiness corporations.[29] Many other countries resisted leaving their food security vulnerable to global markets. Small farmers and peasants joined in protesting the anticipated impacts of GATT agreements for local food markets, rural livelihoods and cultures, and the environment.[30] However, the forces of agricultural trade liberalization prevailed, signaling a change in food and farming, not only in Canada and the US but globally.

Canadian agriculture had been built around exports, but the GATT agreements paved the way for additional trade agreements in North America. Canadian agri-food exports quadrupled following the Canada-US Free Trade Agreement (CUSTA) of 1989, the NAFTA of 1994, and the WTO Agreement on Agriculture (AoA) of 1995. As in the US, these major trade agreements have been followed by numerous other Canadian bilateral and multilateral agreements that have erased virtually all barriers to agricultural trade.

Agricultural trade in Canada and elsewhere is largely limited to multinational agribusiness corporations, virtually eliminating direct farmer participation. Many international transactions take place “within large multinational corporations,” rather than “among nations.” One exception to such transactions has been the Canadian Wheat Board (CWB), which is a western Canadian collective marketing agency. Canadian farmers were required by law to allow the CWB to negotiate sales of wheat and barley on their behalf, which is seen as a threat to free trade in the global marketplace. Corporate pressures to establish neo-liberal free-trade policies have recently forced the CWB to become a voluntary marketing organization, freeing individual larger producers to negotiate their own sales. [31]

The only other sectors of Canadian agriculture left under protection from international competition are poultry, egg and dairy farms. These are the only sectors of the Canadian farm economy that have been consistently profitable. Supply management systems limit production to the needs of the domestic market, and farmers are assured of prices that will cover their production costs for the limited production. This price assurance is only possible with trade restrictions on imports of cheaper products from elsewhere. The remaining programs are under threat from the proposed Trans-Pacific Partnership.

Supply management programs have been critical in preserving the viability of thousands of small family farms in Canada. Similar supply management programs also preserved thousands of family farms in the US, until they were eliminated to facilitate international trade agreements long before NAFTA. The last supply management programs to be phased out in the US were for specialty crops – tobacco and peanuts. A loss of small family farms similar to that experienced in the US can be expected as these programs are eliminated in Canada. As in the US, Canadian farm policies have focused on mono-functionality and economic efficiency to promote international trade rather than domestic food security. With few exceptions, Canadian food security and the economic well-being of Canadian farmers are being left to the vagaries of global markets.

North American Free Trade Agreement. The trilateral trade agreement of 1994 among the US, Canada, and Mexico, or NAFTA, has had major negative impacts on family farmers in all three countries. However, the greatest negative impacts have likely been in Mexico, where the agreement accelerated agricultural industrialization, particularly in the northern regions of the country. NAFTA clearly refocused Mexican farm policies on production of agricultural crops for export rather than production for local and domestic consumption. Large industrial farms have been established in proximity to the US border to export labor-intensive crops, particularly fruits and vegetables, to the United States. Heavily subsidized imports from the US, particularly corn, have depressed domestic prices and eliminated essential sources of cash income for Mexican farm families.

The effects of NAFTA on Mexican agriculture appear to be very similar to the negative impacts of the Green Revolution in India and Africa. As corn prices in Mexico plummeted by 66 percent between 1993 and 2005, many farmers with significant debts lost their farms.[32] An estimated 1.1 million small farmers and 1.4 million other Mexicans who depended on the farm sector were left without work. This made land available for acquisition by foreign corporations that consolidated prime farmland into large plantations. While the price of corn paid to Mexican farmers dropped by more than one-half, the deregulated retail price of tortillas more than doubled.[33] The percent of Mexico’s rural population earning less than the minimum cash income needed to purchase food grew by nearly 50 percent in the agreement’s first three years.[34] Current agricultural policies in Mexico seem destined to continue the trend toward fewer farms, larger farms, and increasing corporate control of agriculture.

The rhetoric of the Mexican farm policy is similar to the rhetoric of US and Canadian farm policy. They “seek to increase farm productivity by making use of the human capital and its natural resources in a sustainable way.”[35] The government provides technical assistance programs that promote efficient water management, soil conservation, and use of improved seeds and fertilizer. However, the stated goal is “to move from subsistence farming to consolidated agriculture that is more integrated with markets.”[36] This suggests that food security in Mexico will be left to the global market – primarily to trade with the US and Canada. To ensure this transition, the Mexican government is stressing the adoption of new technologies and cooperative networking among small farms to achieve economies of scale. Based on the experiences of the US, Canada, and other so-called developed economies, current Mexican farm policies leave the future food security of Mexico to the vagaries of global markets and thus very much in doubt.

Advancing age of family farmers. Another major challenge to family farmers in North America is the advancing age of farmers. The average age of principal farm operators in 2006-2007 was 57.1 yrs. in the United States, 53.3 yrs. for Canada, and 51.8 yrs. in Mexico.[37] Many of the older farmers in the US and Canada were able to pay for their farmland in earlier times and likely have continued farming more as their chosen way of life rather than a meaningful source of farm income. Family farms such as these are not likely to be replaced with other family farms. The average age of farmers continues to climb in all three countries because fewer rural young people are staying on or returning to the farms where they were raised. Young people without farm backgrounds are beginning to operate small farms in the US and Canada, many producing for local niche markets, in rural and urban areas, but not enough to make up for those leaving conventional farms.

Advocates of industrial agriculture have shown little concern about the advancing age of farmers. Fewer young farmers are needed to replace aging farmers because as farms became larger the number of farmers needed naturally becomes smaller. Young people haven’t been choosing farming as their occupation because they haven’t been needed with declining farm numbers. However, the advancing age of farmers is an indication of the continuing decline in family farms. Many of the extended families of today’s aging farmers have long since left the family farm and have no intention of returning. When such farmers retire, sell their farms, or die, their land will be farmed by large industrial farmers. Many of these industrial farmers will not live in close proximity to their new farmland and thus will feel no sense of personal connectedness to the land or to the community. If current trends continue, more farms are destined to become mono-functional farm businesses, rather than multifunctional family farms.

Lack of public research and education. Much of the knowledge and wisdom that will be needed to sustain multifunctional family farms resides in the hearts and minds of today’s aging farmers. Industrial agriculture continues to dominate public research and educational agendas, particularly the Land Grant Universities that traditionally supported family farming. As a result, many of the multifunctional family farmers have turned to learning from each other rather than from the so-called experts. Fortunately, mentorship and collaborative learning, while chosen by necessity, may actually turn out to be an essential aspect of sustainable farming in the future. Even if public research and education institutions were to shift their priorities back to family farming, the wisdom needed for multifunctional farming can only be gained through personal experience or passed on through personal relationships. Unfortunately, when today’s aging farmers retire or die, their personal knowledge and wisdom will go with them.

Meanwhile, the public research and educational agenda continues to be dominated by development of labor- and management-extensive or simplifying agricultural technologies, such as genetically modified organisms (GMOs), concentrated animal feeding operations (CAFO) and GPS-guided precision agriculture systems. New and “better” genetically engineered seeds, routine animal medication, and sophisticated GPS technologies reduce the need for skilled labor and simplify farm management. On the other hand, farming practices that rely on selecting and saving seeds, protecting animal health, and using basic machines and scale-appropriate technologies increase reliance on skilled labor and thoughtful, intelligent management. Farming in the future need not rely on the drudgery labor of farming in the past or be “low-tech” in order to be multifunctional. It will require more thinking workers and working thinkers.

Lack of access to land. Young people who do choose farming as their occupation face a major challenge in gaining access to land. Prices of farmland are at record high levels in the US, as a consequence of expanding demand in global markets and domestic biofuel subsidies and mandates. The transfer of land from parent to child may be difficult due to high land values, particularly in cases of multiple siblings who expect to share an estate. Such farms are typically sold outside the family and the inheritance divided among the siblings. The highest bidders for the land are likely to be large farming operations with no personal sense of connectedness to any particular farm or community, other than perhaps their original “home farm.”

The new farmers producing for niche markets, most of whom did not grow up on farms, face even greater challenges. Few are likely to have an inheritance to invest in farmland and the younger would-be farmers are not likely to have significant savings to invest in farm land. In addition, it is far easier to get a commercial loan to finance a large corporate contract livestock operation than to finance a small organic farm. Government programs for “beginning farmers” are of primary benefit to new commodity producers, not new farmers who produce for local markets, in spite of recent efforts of the USDA to accommodate farmers producing for local markets. Given the current advanced age of owners of farmland in the US, as much as 70 percent of US farmland may change hands over the next two decades.[38] Non-farm investors already own about 30 percent of all US farmland, and large private equity investors have become major competitors in land markets. Access to farmland for multifunctional family farmers is a challenge not likely to be met without significant changes in land tenure policies in the US and Canada.

Reluctance to cooperate. Today’s smaller family farms that are producing for local niche markets will need to “scale up” their operations, if they are to succeed in creating and supporting a sustainable food system in the future. If they are to scale-up without losing their social and ecological integrity, they must learn to cooperate rather than compete – including forming and sustaining cooperative relationships with their customers. Their success will depend on their willingness and ability to sustain a meaningful sense of personal connectedness with others who share their social and ethical values, including their commitment to agricultural sustainability.

In meeting this challenge, literally thousands of farmer alliances, collaboratives, networks, and food hubs are being established across the US and Canada.[39] It is critically important that these new food networks follow the organizational principles of earlier cooperative organizations if they are to maintain their multifunctionality and thus their sustainability. “A cooperative food system involves an interdependent web of mutually beneficial activities that include the production, processing, distribution, wholesaling, retailing, consumption, and disposal of food. It is based on a fundamental commitment to cooperation and democratic processes, while avoiding the winner-take-all competitive ethos that drives the dominant food system… It is interested in community economic development, social capital formation, just livelihoods, food security, and environmental care as much as profits. And like other food systems, cooperative food systems can occur at any scale: they can be part of a local food system and operate within a particular place; they can be part of a regional or national food system…; or they can be part of a worldwide system of cooperation, much like the fair-trade movement.”[40]

The economic necessity for members of these new organizations or alliances to cooperate rather than compete will create significant challenges farmers, even for many of today’s multifunctional farmers. Farmers traditionally have prided themselves on their independence. Many simply have not thought it necessary to understand the science or art of social relationships, at least not beyond their close friends and family members. However, those who meet the challenges of cooperation, who master the art and science of social relationships, may well find it to be one of the most economically and personally rewarding aspects of family farming in the future.

Family farms at a crossroads. Whether deserved or not, family farmers still hold a position of respect and esteem among the people of North America. However, most North Americans don’t realize the relentless pressures that family farmers have been under to abandon their historic role as caretakers of the earth and keepers of cultural values in order to survive economically. Many have failed economically, and the remaining family farmers are told they must manage their farms as a business, not a way of life, if they expect to survive. Family farmers today are being pressured to join the industrial business class and become managers of money, machinery, and laborers, instead of traditional “farmers.” Their “fair share” of benefits will be determined by global markets, not by their ability to “feed, clothe, and lodge the whole body of people,” as suggested by Adam Smith.

Many of the surviving farmer have remained true to the principles of traditional family farming, but many others have not. As a result, any two farms that are owned and operated by families may have very different implications for the well-being of society and the future of humanity, as well as for the two farm families. Family farmers in North America are at a crossroads. Economic globalization of the food system is reaching a point of crisis, meaning a time of decision for the future of family farmers. Farm families are being forced to choose between farming as a way of life and farming as a bottom-line business: the former at the highest esteem and the latter at the lowest esteem within past cultures. A fundamental question is whether the characteristics of family farms associated with their position of high esteem in the past are still relevant today, or alternatively, whether economic efficiency should be the new measure of a family farm’s true worth.

Do Family Farms Matter?

The family farm controversy. Family farms obviously are important to farm families but is their survival essential or even significant for society as a whole or the future of humanity? Farm families represent a very small percentage of the total population of the US and Canada and a rapidly decreasing percentage of the population of Mexico. Family farms also account for a small and shrinking portion of the agricultural economy. As economies shift from agrarian to industrial, the economic importance of agriculture declines and the economic significance of family farmers declines even faster. Those who focus on agricultural productivity or economic efficiency often view family farms as nostalgic relics of the past that will soon be replaced by more economically efficient farm businesses. Those who value traditional family farms are sometimes referred to as idealists who long for a return to some utopian vision of the past that never actually existed.

The controversies surrounding family farms versus industrial farms tend to center on questions related to agricultural sustainability. The IAASTD Global Report, Agriculture at a Crossroads, states: “Sustainable development is about meeting current needs without compromising the ability of future generations to meet their own needs. Within this context, sustainability is envisaged within three key dimensions: social, environmental and economic, all three of which have direct and indirect linkages to agriculture. It is indisputable that agriculture as a sector cannot meet this goal on its own. Agriculture, however, fulfills a series of additional goals besides food production. Last but by no means least, agriculture ensures the delivery of a range of ecosystem services. In view of a globally sustainable form of development, the importance of this role may increase and become central for human survival on this planet.”[41] Can family farms meet the needs of the present without diminishing opportunities for the future?

Humanity is even more dependent on farming today than in the times when hunting and gathering was the dominant food system. The sustainability of human life on earth depends on the sustainability of agriculture. A sustainability of agriculture must be economically viable, but economic sustainability cannot be ensured through productivity or economic efficiency. The sustainability of agriculture depends on the willingness and ability of farmers to sustain the long-run productivity of the natural and human resources upon which agricultural productivity ultimately depends, as well as the economically efficient use of those resources.

Sustainable farms must be intentionally multifunctional: they must be managed for ecological, social, and economic integrity. Will family farms remain multifunctional farms or will they become mono-functional farm businesses? This is a decision that will not and cannot be made solely by farmers but also must be made by society through individual choices as consumers and collective choices among agricultural and trade policies. This is not a decision to be taken lightly. The future of humanity may well depend on the future of multifunctional family farmers.

Multifunctionality of farms and farmers. Are operators of farms really farmers or are they business-men or -women? What does it mean to be a farmer? Historically, a farmer has always been one who cultivates land, cares for livestock, or otherwise operates a farm. The English word farmer has varied origins: from Middle English, fermer, fermour (“steward,”), partly from Old French fermier (“husbandman”), and from Medieval Latin firmarius (“one who rents land”).[42]The English word farm comes from Middle English word, ferme, farme (“rent, revenue, produce, stewardship, meal, feast”), from Old English feorm, fearm, farm ("meaning provisions, food, supplies, possessions, stores, feast, entertainment, haven"), from Proto-Germanic fermō ("means of living, subsistence"), and from Proto-Indo-European perk - ("life, strength, force"). It is related also to Old English words such as feormian ("to provision, sustain"), and feorh ("life, spirit"), and Icelandic word fjör (“life, vitality, vigour, animation”).[43]

These root meanings suggest that economics has always been an important aspect of farming and farms. Root meanings such as “rent, revenue, subsistence, and means of living” suggest that farming has always been a means for families to make an economic living. Farming also has been about producing food for others, for communities and societies, which is often achieved through a farm economy. Root meanings such as “provision, food supplies, and purveyor” also suggest that farming has always been seen as an essential part of the larger food economy.

However, farming has also been about providing sustenance for the mental and spiritual needs of farm families, communities, and societies, as well as providing physical nourishment. Root meanings such as “spirit, entertainment, feast, and haven” suggest that farms represent something more than physical and economic sustenance. Equally important, the roots of farms and farming strongly suggest a moral or ethical commitment to the long-term well-being of communities, societies, and humanity. Root meanings such as “stewardship, strength, firm, solid, security, and sustain” reflect a historical commitment of farmers to a permanent agriculture in order to ensure the durability of sustainable societies and the sustainability of humanity.

Throughout nearly all of human history, farms have been multifunctional and most farmers have been committed to the basic ideology of sustainability: attempting to meet the needs of their families and societies without diminishing opportunities for those of future generations. Obviously, farmers have not always succeeded in their multifunctional mission. The fundamental question today is whether farmers of the future should abandon multifunctionality in the pursuit of mono-functional economic efficiency or should continue to embrace multifunctionality in their pursuit of agricultural sustainability.

Many farms of the past obviously were not sustainable, as former great civilizations rose with the increased productivity of their farms and fell when their farmers lost the ability to meet the needs of their societies because they had degraded their environment. Obviously, many early farmers in the US and Canada were not stewards of the land. That said, many family farms today still retain a commitment to intentional multifunctional farming – to sustainability: balancing the need to make a living for the family with their need to be respectful members of their communities and responsible stewards of the land for the future of humanity. Family farmers today have the benefit of learning from past failures and the potential for a far greater understanding of how best to work with nature and society to ensure long-run sustainability. These lessons from the past can be acknowledged and addressed by today’s family farmers rather than discarded as useless relics of indigenous cultures.

Intentional multifunctionality. Multifunctionality has been a primary focus of work in the so-called developing countries of the world, but it is equally important to the future of industrial countries, including the US and Canada. The IAASTD Global Report, reflecting a consensus of 400 scientists representing 58 different countries, confirmed that agriculture is inherently multifunctional: “It provides food, feed, fiber, fuel and other goods. It also has a major influence on other essential ecosystem services such as water supply and carbon sequestration or release. Agriculture plays an important social role, providing employment and a way of life. Both agriculture and its products are a medium of cultural transmission and cultural practices worldwide. Agriculturally based communities provide a foundation for local economies and are an important means for countries to secure their territories.”[44] The key question is whether the multifunctionality of a specific approach to agriculture or system of farming is consistent with sustainability.

Presumably, no farmer would intentionally manage his or her farm in ways that needlessly degrade the natural ecosystems or diminish the quality of life in the communities in which the farm operates. Thus, intentional multifunctionality implies conscious, purposeful farm management decisions and actions that have positive, rather than negative, impacts on the natural ecosystems, communities, and economies. Farms that are managed strictly as businesses are also multifunctional, since they have inevitable ecological, social, and economic consequences. However, the ecological and social consequences of mono-functional farm businesses are almost certain to be negative. Family farms are unique because they have a logical motivation to be intentionally multifunctional because the social and ecological consequences of their functionality are inseparable from the overall well-being of the farm families. Thus, the ecological and social consequences of multifunctional family farming could logically be expected to be quite different from the consequences of mono-functional farm businesses.

Giving priority to economic efficiency invariably leads to extraction and exploitation of the natural and human resources that ultimately must sustain long-run productivity – in agriculture as well as all other sectors of economies. Certainly, farm businesses can be managed in ways that limit their inevitable pollution of air, water, and soil with chemical and biological contaminants. They can even substitute renewable for non-renewable inputs and resources. Operators of farm businesses can also consider the impacts of their management decisions on their land, their neighbors, and the people who eat their food. Such strategies explicitly show respect for the inherent multifunctionality of farming and obviously can reduce its negative social and ecological impacts. However, farm businesses can minimize their negative impacts only to the extent that doing so does not compromise their economic bottom-lines. Giving priority to economic efficiency has unavoidably negative social and ecological consequences which threaten long-run economic sustainability.

Economic mono-functionality. Economic value is individual, instrumental, and impersonal.[45] Economic value accrues to individuals rather than to communities or societies as wholes. It is instrumental, in that an economic transaction is a means to an end, rather than something done because of its inherent worth. As a result, the economy places a premium on the present relative to the future. For example, it makes no economic sense to invest in anything if the returns are expected to accrue only after the investor is dead. Since life is inherently uncertain, investments with quicker returns are valued higher than comparable investments with longer-term payouts. That’s the reason borrowers pay interest and lenders charge interest. There is an economic cost associated with delaying the potential gratification from an economic asset until sometime in the future. Furthermore, there are no economic incentives to be caretakers of the land or to care about communities if the benefits will accrue solely to someone else at some time in the future.

Economic value is impersonal, because if something cannot be bought, sold, or traded from one person to another, it has no economic value. Social values are personal; the particular persons involved in a social relationship matter. Social values evolve into ethical values, as people learn they should show the same empathy, compassion, and respect for everyone that they show for those they know personally: a personal ethic. Many family farmers also feel personal connections to their farms, which evolve into their personal “land ethics.” Many people quite logically and rationally invest significant amounts of their time, energy, and money in things they value socially and ethically, even when there is no economic incentive to do so.

Mono-functional farmers, on the other hand, will only make investments in society and nature if their investments are expected to yield economic benefits, which are short run in nature. They will make investments that are socially and ecologically responsible only if they are profitable or economically valuable as well. Thus, mono-functional farm businesses will not make the multi-generational investments in society and nature that are essential for agricultural sustainability. Since all economic value ultimately is derived from nature by way of society, mono-functional farms are not even economically sustainable.

Consequences of corporatization. The question of ownership and control is critical to determining the functionality and sustainability of a family farm. Another farm financial crisis like the 1980s is highly unlikely in the US. Large, specialized farming operations have continued to grow even larger, but most important, farms have become increasingly controlled by large, multi-national agribusiness corporations. The corporations typically don’t own these farms or feedlots but control their production process through various contractual arrangements. Contracts range from those specifying a selling price or use of a specific herbicide to controlling virtually every aspect of the production and marketing process. More than 95 percent of poultry[46] and 70 percent of hogs[47] in the US are produced under comprehensive corporate production contracts. More than 90 percent of all soybeans, corn, and cotton grown in the US is produced using patented genetically engineered seeds requiring corporate licensing agreements. [48] Corporate control of US agriculture is widespread in the US.

Various studies have indicated that maximum economic efficiencies of large-scale farming operations are reached at farm sizes far smaller than is claimed by advocates of industrial agriculture and were probably largely exhausted in the US by the 1950s or 1960s.[49] The logical motives of continued corporate consolidation are market power, which brings financial power and ultimately political power. Market power can be used to extract unnecessary profits from consumers, producers, and nature. Contract growers can be pressured to minimize production costs through practices that degrade the land and natural environment and diminish the quality of life of people in rural communities. Corporate political influence can thwart government regulations that might otherwise protect natural and human resources from exploitation.

Unlike corporations, multifunctional family farmers are real people, they have purely personal connections to their farms and to others in their communities. They feel an ethical responsibility to care for their land and care about their neighbors and customers. Their social and ethical values can affect their decisions, even if they function through family corporations. Corporations are not real people; they have no ethical or social values. Corporations function to serve the common interest of their shareholders. Family corporations can reflect the shared social and ethical values of the family, which they can prioritize over economic values.

The investors or shareholders in large, publicly-traded corporations also have social and ethical values. However, with thousands or millions of investors from many different nationalities, religions, and philosophies, investors in large multi-national corporations are highly unlikely to share any social or ethical values in common. The only common value shared by stockholders in such corporations is the desire to enhance the economic value of their investments, particularly for companies with blocks of shares owned by pension funds and mutual funds. High-speed electronic trading of corporate stock makes connections between transitory investors and corporate management even less personal and thus more economic.

Even so, the prevailing agricultural ideology seems to be that continued corporatization and industrialization of agriculture are the only logical means of providing enough food for a growing global population. Agricultural producers in North America are told they must continue increasing production for exports to countries that are unable to meet the food needs of their people. The basic logic or reasoning supporting this ideology is: Global population is destined to grow from the current seven-plus billion to at least nine billion people by the middle of this century. More people obviously will require more food. And, a corporately-controlled, industrial agriculture is the only logical means of increasing global food production.

A basic flaw in this logic is that with greater scarcity and rising costs of fossil energy and the progression of global climate change, industrial agriculture inevitably will become less productive and less economically efficient over time and may not even survive the twenty-first century. Genetic engineering and precision farming are just the latest in a long line of technologies designed to “prop up” a system of farming that is inherently incapable of agricultural sustainability. Nations that continue to depend on industrial agriculture for short-term food security or long-term agricultural sustainability face a future of growing dependence on a few large multi-national food corporations that have no personal or ethical commitment or allegiance to any nation or the future of humanity.

Failure of agricultural industrialization. Faith in the future of industrial agriculture apparently is based on its record of increasing productivity over the past 50 to 60 years. Admittedly, yields of crops per acre or hectare of farmland in terms of production of meat, milk, and eggs, per bushel or ton of feed have increased during this period. However, virtually all of these increases have been linked directly or indirectly to an increased reliance on previously abundant and inexpensive fossil energy. Cheap nitrogen fertilizers were readily available because of an abundance of natural gas. Climate-controlled buildings for livestock were economically feasible because of low-cost fuel for heating and ventilation. Fossil fuels provided energy not only for traction but also for the manufacturing of machinery. Deep-well irrigation likewise depends on low-cost energy to pump and distribute water. Most pesticides are also fossil-energy based materials. Industrial agriculture is inherently fossil-energy dependent.

In the United States, for example, approximately ten calories of fossil energy is required for each calorie of food energy produced.[50] About two-thirds of this total is associated with food processing, manufacturing, transportation, packaging and other processes of the industrial food system. Even at the farm level, industrial agriculture requires about three kcals of fossil energy per kcal of food produced. In addition, industrial agriculture is impractical, if not impossible, without an industrial system of food processing and distribution. The economic competitiveness of industrial agriculture depends on a fossil-energy-dependent food system.

Energy experts differ on their estimates of how much recoverable fossil energy is left to be extracted from the earth. Some experts claim that most economically recoverable fossil energy reserves will be depleted within fifty years while others believe there is enough fossil energy for another 100 to 150 years. However, there is no disagreement that the remaining reserves of fossil energy will be more physically challenging, environmentally risky, and economically costly to extract, as is evident with the “fracking” process required to extract shale gas and deep-sea drilling for oil and natural gas. Beyond some point for each fossil energy source, production will peak; there will be less fossil energy available each year thereafter. Each time demand increases relative to supplies, prices of fossil energy will rise – and eventually will rise dramatically.

With increases in fossil energy demand of 2.5 percent per year, which is typical of recent years, total fossil energy demand would double every 30 years. This means twice as much fossil energy would be needed by 2045, four times as much by 2075, and eight times as much by 2105. Renewable energy from wind, water, passive solar, and photovoltaic cells eventually must replace fossil energy in agriculture as well as elsewhere in the economy. However, renewable energy must be captured, organized, concentrated, and stored before it is suitable for a wide range of current energy uses. Thus, useful energy from renewable sources will likely be far less abundant and more expensive than the fossil energy of the past century that was used to develop and support an industrial agriculture.

In addition, industrial agriculture places similarly unsustainable demands on groundwater or aquifers used for irrigation, half of which has already been depleted by some estimates.[51],[52] Other estimates indicate that the earth's mineable phosphorus reserves could be depleted in 50 to 100 years, with a peak occurring around 2030.[53] Industrial agriculture is also destroying the natural productivity of soils through erosion, salinization, and agrochemical contamination. Fertilizers and agricultural pesticides also are major contributors to pollution of groundwater, streams, and estuaries. Industrial agriculture is a major contributor to global climate change, and the related weather instability will be a major challenge in sustaining productivity to provide global food security and agricultural sustainability.[54] In summary, industrial agriculture depletes the natural resource base that supports its productivity and pollutes the natural environment that sustains the health of humanity. Industrial agriculture cannot possibly provide long-run food security or agricultural sustainability.

Contrary to popular belief, the inability of industrial agriculture to provide even short-term food security is readily apparent in the United States and Canada. In fact, a larger percentage of people in the US are “food insecure” today than during the 1960s, prior to the final phases of agricultural industrialization. As indicated previously, food security means that everyone has enough wholesome and nutritious food to support healthy, active lifestyles. About one-in-six residents of the US and one-in-eight Canadians is classified as “food insecure.” The prevalence of hunger among children is higher, with about one-in-five US children and one-in-six Canadian children living in food insecure homes. [55], [56]

In industrial nations, many people can get enough food to satisfy their hunger only by buying cheap industrial calorie-rich food products that fail to meet their nutritional needs for healthy, active lifestyles. As a result, diet-related illnesses in the US are rampant, including obesity and related diseases such as diabetes, hypertension, heart failure, and various types of cancers. Obesity-related illnesses alone are projected to claim about one-in-five dollars spent for health care in the US by 2020 – erasing virtually all of the gains made in improving public health over the past several decades.[57] Total healthcare costs in the US are almost twice as great as total cost of food.[58] As might be expected, diet-related illnesses are most prevalent in lower-income, food-insecure homes. Food security depends on food quality, not simply calories.

A growing body of scientific evidence links the industrialization of agriculture to foods that are rich in calories and poor in essential nutrients, which have helped fuel the epidemic of obesity and other diet-related illnesses.[59] The rising costs of diet-related health care have paralleled the industrialization of agriculture. Industrial agriculture in North America has produced an abundance of cheap food, but it has failed to provide food security or sustain public health. Food security, as well as agricultural sustainability, will require a fundamental change in farming systems: a return to multifunctionality.

Failure of the Green Revolution. Agricultural industrialization has also failed to provide food security in the so-called developing nations. Development experts attribute the persistence of global hunger to increases in population made possible by increased food production during the Green Revolution. They argue that infant mortality has declined due to better nutrition. However, many of those living in developing nations have a very different view. Stacia and Kristof Nordin who have worked for decades with farmers in Malawi, Africa point out the consequences of dependence on industrial agricultural technologies: “Many [farmers] have found themselves caught in a cycle of dependency that has actually left them worse off than before the Green Revolution took hold. People are finding that they are forced to sell off larger amounts of their yields in order to cover the cost of these growing expenditures. The selling of their crops has deprived many families of annual food reserves, nutritional requirements, and [potential] increased standards of living.”[60]

In the words of Vandava Shiva, a globally-prominent and highly-respected ecologist and Indian food activist: “The Green Revolution has been a failure. It has led to reduced genetic diversity, increased vulnerability to pests, soil erosion, water shortages, reduced soil fertility, micronutrient deficiencies, soil contamination, reduced availability of nutritious food crops for the local population, the displacement of vast numbers of small farmers from their land, rural impoverishment and increased tensions and conflicts. The beneficiaries have been the agrochemical industry, large petrochemical companies, manufacturers of agricultural machinery, dam builders and large landowners.”[61]

Admittedly, the Green Revolution was a success from the perspective of economic efficiency or productivity. It turned multifunctional family farms into mono-functional farm businesses. However, the fact that previous food-importing countries become exporters of grain simply meant the new industrial producers were exporting their products to more profitable markets elsewhere rather than providing food to the poor and hungry people at home. The potential reduction in food prices for those living in the cities were often too small to make any real difference in hunger. As the US and Canadian experiences have clearly demonstrated, cheap food is not the solution to hunger. In addition, lower production costs may be offset by increased profits of food processors and distributors, and the nutritional quality of food may be diminished. Even in cases where it may appear that industrial agriculture has succeeded, it eventually is destined to fail because of its lack of ecological and social sustainability.

But is there an alternative? If large, mono-functional farms can’t feed the world, can global food security and agricultural sustainability be provided by small, multifunctional farms? Contrary to a widely promoted belief, industrializing global agriculture – meaning replacing the remaining small, multifunctional, diversified farms with large, mono-functional, specialized farms – is not the only means of increasing global food production. Industrial agriculture advocates seem to ignore that small multifunctional farms already account for at least 70 percent of global food production, according to the United Nations Environmental Program.[62] Furthermore, industrial agriculture is more efficient than non-industrial agriculture only in terms of the number of people employed and the costs of labor and management. Industrial agriculture is not more efficient in terms of production per dollar invested, per calorie of fossil energy used, or in terms of resource degradation and pollution per calorie of food produced. It is not even more efficient in terms of production per acre or hectare of land.

Miguel Altieri of the University of California elaborates on the productivity advantage for small farms.[63] “A large farm may produce more corn per hectare than a small farm in which the corn is grown as part of a polyculture that also includes beans, squash, potatoes, and fodder. But, productivity in terms of harvestable products per unit area of polycultures developed by smallholders is higher than under a single crop with the same level of management [emphasis added]. Yield advantages can range from 20 percent to 60 percent, because polycultures reduce losses due to weeds (by occupying space that weeds might otherwise occupy), insects, and diseases (because of the presence of multiple species), and make more efficient use of the available resources of water, light, and nutrients.”[64]

Major comprehensive studies have documented the potential for increasing the productivity of intensively-managed, small-scale farms by relying on diversified, organic, sustainable farming methods. For example, a 2008 United Nations study of farming methods in 24 African countries found that organic or near-organic farming resulted in yield increases of more than 100 percent.[65] As Peter Rossett of the Institute for Food and Development Policy explains: “Here at the Institute, we've reviewed the data from every country for which it's available, comparing the productivity of smaller farms versus larger farms. For every country for which data is available, smaller farms are anywhere from 200 to 1,000 percent more productive per unit area. When you grow one crop all by itself, you may get a lot of that one crop, but you're not using the ecological space – the land and water – very efficiently. Large farmers generally have monocultures because they are easier to fully mechanize.”[66]

A doubling of production on the small farms that currently provide food for 70 percent of global population would allow them to support a 70 percent increase in global population, even if there were no further increase in production from industrial farms – clearly enough to meet the expected basic global food needs of 2050 and beyond. Therefore, global food security does not depend on continued increases in productivity in industrial agricultural countries such as the US and Canada. The challenge in these countries is to increase the sustainability of agriculture rather than to increase agricultural yields or productivity.

Most of the research comparing conventional farming with more sustainable alternatives focuses on organic farming. Long-term studies in the US have shown that well-managed organic farming systems – using organic practices common in the US, Canada, and northern Mexico – can produce yields comparable to conventional farming systems.[67],[68] A comprehensive review of numerous comparisons which was published in the journal Nature indicate that organic yields tend to be lower, at least under some conditions. Summarizing a large number of studies, the authors found organic deficits averaging as high as 34 percent under conditions least favorable for organic but only 13 percent under the best organic management practices. Organic yields were actually higher in some situations, and deficits averaged as low as 5 percent for some crops and growing conditions. The study concluded: “Under certain conditions—that is, with good management practices, particular crop types and growing conditions—organic systems can thus nearly match conventional yields, whereas under others it at present cannot.”[69] But, as others have pointed out, yields are not the primary motivation for organic or sustainable agriculture.[70]

Yields “comparable to” current yields will be more than adequate to provide food security in the US with an otherwise sustainable food system. Yield differences between conventional and organic farming were greatest for field crops, such as corn and soybeans, used primarily for livestock feed and biofuels. Simply reducing the proportion of animal products in North American diets and taking animals out of feedlots, returning them to their natural roles as foragers and scavengers, would free up a significant percentage of total tillable acres for food production. The primary challenge to family farmers in North America is sustainability, not productivity.

In addition, with multifunctional farming the need for fossil energy for food production would be greatly reduced, scarcity of water and other natural resources would be less restricting of food production, nature could accommodate the agricultural wastes, and soil productivity could be restored, while sequestering large quantities of greenhouse gasses and mitigating global climate change in the process. All of these changes would move humanity closer to food security and agricultural sustainability.

Sustainability depends on intentional multifunctionality. The IAASTD Global Report cited previously concluded that agricultural production systems must change radically to meet future demand. It called for governments to pay more attention to small-scale farmers and sustainable farming practices.[71] These international food experts challenge the myth that industrial agriculture is more efficient in any sense other than in reducing agricultural employment and maximizing economic returns for those who have the capital to invest in an industrial farming operation. Increasingly, food security experts are now calling for a shift in global agricultural development programs to focus on supporting a multifunctional agriculture, capable of providing global food security while protecting the natural environment, preserving rural communities, and honoring indigenous knowledge and cultures – meeting the needs of the present and future.

A strong and growing sustainable agriculture movement in already underway in the US and Canada: with names including organic, ecological, biodynamic, holistic, permaculture, practical and innovative.[72] However, the sustainability of North American agriculture may ultimately depend on North American farmers being willing to learn agroecology, permaculture, and other approaches to sustainable farming that are more common to farming in other parts of the world. Mexican farmers may have a distinct advantage in this regard, because many have not abandoned the more sustainable farming and land tenure practices of earlier times. Supportive farm policies could help families preserve the multifunctionality of their farms. Farmers in the US may have the greatest difficulty because US agriculture is still dominated by the corporate industrial paradigm of agriculture. Farmers in Canada have a more recent history of supply management to meet their domestic food needs but also have the greatest economic dependence on agricultural exports.

The industrial model of food production seemed to make sense in an earlier world where people were relatively few, fossil energy was plentiful and inexpensive, natural resources were abundant, and nature seemed capable of assimilating and neutralizing any amount of toxins and wastes. None of these conditions are true of the world of today. The challenge of the future will be to provide meaningful employment for more people, to transition from nonrenewable to renewable resources, and to reduce pollution to levels that can be assimilated or otherwise accommodated by nature.

The global food system of the future must balance the need for greater productivity and resource efficiency, with the resilience to thrive under uncertain climatic conditions, and the capacity to renew and regenerate the soil, water, air, energy, and other resources needed to sustain productivity. Rather than being mechanistic, specialized, standardized, and centrally controlled, farms of the future must be organismic, holistic, diverse, multifunctional, decentralized farms that are “ways of life,” as well as means of making a living. Family farms have the potential to meet these criteria and have a natural advantage in fulfilling the multiple needs of their societies and of humanity in the future.

The sustainable food systems of the future are likely to be local community-based systems that are guided by collaboration and cooperation, rather than global corporate-based systems guided by competition and domination. The smaller, diversified, sustainable family farms of the future will provide greater economic opportunities for people in rural areas and cleaner, healthier rural environments – slowing and eventually reversing the rural-to-urban population migration of the past. People of the future, in all nations of the world, will have not only enough calories to meet their energy needs but they will have access to enough nutritious foods to meet their complete nutritional needs for healthy, active lifestyles. Healthier people and lower costs of health care will result in healthier economies and societies.

All of these benefits are possible with existing knowledge and technologies, and the positive possibilities for the future are even greater. Large, mono-functional industrial farms cannot provide global food security for either the present or the future, but multifunctional sustainable family farms could provide both. All it would take is a fundamental change in thinking and the courage to act in the face of corporate opposition. The future of multifunctional family farms is critical to global food security and agricultural sustainability.

Diversity of Family-Operated Farms

Official definitions of family farms. The 2014 “Dialogue on Family Farms in North America” clearly demonstrated that family farms are very diverse or heterogeneous in nature.[73] Farming operations owned and controlled by families range from small urban market gardens to large multinational corporations, such as Cargill. As indicated previously, there is no consensus regarding the definition of a “family farm” for purposes of farm policy. The Economic Research Service (ERS) of the USDA defines family farms as “those whose principal operator, and people related to the principal operator by blood or marriage, own most of the farm business.”[74] The principal operator is the person who is responsible for the on-site, day-to-day business decisions.

Under the ERS definition, family farms represent 97.6 percent of all US farms and are responsible for 85 percent of US farm production. When consideration is given to whether the family provides most of the labor for the farm and to whether the farm utilized most of the labor of the family, the percentages of family farms drops to 87 and 86 percent and the percentage of total production drops to 57 percent and 47 percent respectively. These definitions provide very limited useful information regarding the important question of whether family-owned farms in the US are multifunctional or mono-functional with respect to management.

Statistics Canada defines a family farm as “a farm where the farm family provides much of the capital and labour for the farm. In some cases there are seasonal employees. Many incorporated farms are still considered to be family farms.”[75] Non-family corporations account for 2.4 percent of all Canadian farms. The rest are presumably considered to be family farms. However non-family corporations own ten percent of farms with sales of over $1 million dollars in Canada, which account for just under one-half of total gross farms receipts.[76] The “farm policy definitions” of family farms in Canada and the US appear to be quite similar in classifying virtually all farming operations as family farms and attributing the vast majority of agricultural production to family farms. Unfortunately, such definitions are of very limited benefit in addressing the challenges faced by multifunctional family farms.

Mexican statistics for family farms include those that produce foods to meet the needs of farm families and for sale in local markets, which would exclude virtually all corporate farms. A study conducted by the Ministry of Agriculture, Livestock, Rural Development, Fisheries, and Nutrition (SAGARPA) identified three major groups of family farms: “Subsistence family farms: Food production for on-farm consumption characterized by inadequate productive resources and the need to supplement income with non-farm activities or government aid; Family farms in transition: Production for on-farm consumption and sale, with minor shortages of productive resources; additional sources of income are rarely needed; and Consolidated family farms: Sustainable production and sale in local markets, with no shortage of productive resources; other sources of income may sporadically be required.”[77]

The study concluded that 81.3 percent of Mexico's 5.4 million rural economic units (REU) could be considered family farms. According to the study, 39.6 percent of REUs in Mexico have “business production potential” beyond subsistence farming. The primary exception to family farming in Mexico appears to be farms operated by large US food corporations that rent land in northern Mexico to produce crops for export to the US. None of the current agricultural statistics provide information of significant value in meeting the current challenges to family farms, domestic food security, or the long-term sustainability of North American agriculture.

Family farm definitions include farm businesses. In the US and Canada, farms obviously have become fewer and larger as family farms have been transformed into agricultural businesses. This same trend is apparent in northern Mexico and is being supported by policies of the Mexican government. However, farm size alone does not distinguish between family farms and non-family farms. The existing definitions tend to give some attention to the gradients between family and non-family farms mentioned previously. They include the nature of management, legal ownership, and in the case of Mexico, the destination of production. The source of labor is somewhat ambiguous in US and Canadian definitions. Current definitions fail to consider the source of investment capital or land tenure status, although the vast majority of Mexican family farmers rent rather than own their land.

Perhaps the most obvious and important omission from family farm statistics is the ultimate source of control of farming operations. The US and Canadian definitions both indicate that farm families must be the principal operators, meaning they make the day-to-day management decisions for family farms. However, the basic functionality of the farming operation, of whether it is multifunctional or mono-functional, may be determined far more by various contractual agreements than by the “principal operators” who make day-to-day decisions. The terms of production contracts typically are determined by agribusiness corporations that have far more bargaining power than do even the largest of family farming operations. The terms of corporate contracts obviously reflect the economic interest of corporate investors, and thus give priority to the economic functions of the farming operation. Attention given to social and ecological functions are likely to be limited to minimum compliance with environmental regulations and avoiding potential nuisance law suits of neighbors who endure their negative ecological and social impacts.

The extent to which contracts shift control of the farming operation from the principal operator to the contracting corporation varies greatly, depending on the nature of the contract. A contracted price for a single shipment of grain or livestock represents little transfer of control from the farmer to corporate buyer. Comprehensive production contracts for livestock, such as those typical for large livestock feeding operations, transfers almost complete control of the production process from the principal operator to the contracting corporation. The corporation often specifies the design of production facilities, retains ownership of the feeder livestock, provides the feed, determines heath management practices, and specifies timing of production practices and marketing.[78] The length of the commitment by the operator is essentially determined by the useful life of the production facilities, as financing of construction may be dependent on the contract.

A licensing agreement to grow a genetically modified, herbicide-resistant grain crop transfers control of production practices for the growing season. The license to use the corporations’ GM seeds obligates to the operator to use of the corporation’s herbicides and associated management practices and prohibits saving of seeds for replanting. Producers of fresh fruits and vegetables who become dependent on single corporate buyers are essentially controlled by those corporations, regardless of the length of their contracts. They have no logical alternative markets.

The limited government data available regarding the extent of contracting among family farms and the nature of contractual arrangements are not adequate to be of use in determining the degree of multifunctionality. In matters concerning food security, agricultural sustainability, and the future of humanity, the functionality of farming operations is far more important than whether a family owns and provides day-to-day management for a farming operation. Farms that are owned and operated by families are quite diverse, but the security and sustainability of food systems depends on the specific subset of family farms that are intentionally multifunctional rather than simply family owned and operated. Sustainable farms managed for ecological, social, and economic integrity rather than economic efficiency.

Government Policies for Multifunctional Family Farms

From food security to agricultural sustainability. Over the past several decades, government policies have been focused on mono-functional economic efficiency. While such policies obviously were motivated by good intentions, the negative consequences of an economically mono-functional agriculture are now clearly evident in persistent pockets of food insecurity and the more general rise in diet-related illnesses in the US and Canada. Other countries of the world have experienced similar consequences as they have industrialized their food systems and shifted from multifunctional family farms to mono-functional farm businesses. Mexico is beginning to experience similar consequences in the northern part of the country, as traditional family farms are replaced by corporate farms and people become reliant on food imports from the US.

Food security, domestic and global, has been a logical motive for government policies specific to agriculture and farming in the past, even though such policies obviously failed to provide everyone with access to enough wholesome food to support healthy, active lifestyles. However, with growing concerns about ecological integrity and social equity, the agricultural public policy mandate must extend beyond food security to agricultural sustainability. Food security alone, while necessary, is insufficient to address the long-term challenges to the future of humanity. Agricultural sustainability is inherently a multifunctional concept with ecological, social, and economic dimensions. Thus, farm policies that support and promote agricultural sustainability must support and promote intentional multifunctionality.

As an example of multifunctional farm policy, the concept of food sovereignty has been developed by La Via Campesina as an alternative to food security in formulating farm policy. Food sovereignty is defined as “the right of the world’s peoples to healthy and culturally appropriate food, produced in an ecological and sustainable way, and the right to define their own farming and food systems.”[79] Regardless of whether governments embrace the specific policy agenda of the food sovereignty, the concept provides a significant example of a multifunctional approach to farm policy. Its principles include: : 1) target food for people and not agribusiness and international markets; 2) promote the work of everyone who produces food… and reject policies that seek to eliminate producers or threaten their communities; 3) promote the development of local networks… that link producers and consumers; 4) promote decisions and local control of resources by resisting privatization while emphasizing sharing and sustainability; 5) promote the development and transmission of local knowledge to future generations; 6) promote working together with nature to benefit biodiversity.[80] A seventh and important principle was omitted from the FAO summary: “Smallholder farmers must have direct input into formulating agricultural policies at all levels. Everyone has the right to honest, accurate information and open and democratic decision-making... free from all forms of discrimination. Rural women, in particular, must be granted direct and active decision making on food and rural issues.[81] Food sovereignty goes beyond food security to include ethical, social, and ecological agendas for farm policy.

Regardless of the specific policy agenda chosen, agricultural sustainability will require fundamental changes in farm policies. The greatest obstacle to such changes in North America will be the economic and political power of multinational food corporations and large agribusinesses. Corporate agribusiness, large commodity associations, and even some traditional family farm organizations, have multi-million dollar political campaign budgets that are dedicated to government maintaining programs that subsidize industrial agriculture. They are equally dedicated to defeating policy initiatives that oppose or even question their agenda. They understand that even small government programs that give token support for organic farming, sustainable agriculture, and local niche markets are essential to create a public perception of political objectivity, but they are careful not to allow such perceptions to become reality.

From economic efficiency to multifunctionality. The longest journey begins with the first step, and the first toward redirecting farming toward multifunctional family farms may be to redefine family farms – at least for purposes of public policy. Past definitions or classifications of farms have focused on the economic dimension of farming, such as value of production, net farm income, ownership structure, source of labor, source of capital, and land tenure. Such criteria apparently assume the most important functions of farming, if not its sole function, are economic in nature. Different types of farms are defined simply as different types of farm businesses – as mono-functional rather than multifunctional.

Redefining family farms to reflect their multifunctionality will require the best thinking of the brightest minds and the commitment and persistence of a dedicated coalition of political activists. Accordingly, the Food and Agricultural Organization of the United Nations has assembled a working group to develop a consensus definition of family farms appropriate for purposes of public policy. To be useful in developing farm policies that support food sovereignty, definitions or classifications of family farms must reflect differences in their intentionality. Family farms that are managed multifunctionally must be distinguishable from those managed mono-functionally.

While new definitions of multifunctional family farms may be useful in guiding future farm policies, the necessity for fundamental changes in North America is already abundantly clear. The necessary changes may seem radical to those involved in current farm policy debates; however, fundamental changes in North American farm policy must be made before it is too late to reverse the ecological and social degradation inherent in industrial agriculture. The future of humanity may well depend on transformational rather than incremental change.

Phase out commodity-based farm policies. Public policies currently subsidizing industrial agriculture should deemphasized immediately and phased out over time. All government programs that are linked to specific commodities, including corn, soybeans, wheat, and rice encourage specialization production for globally-traded commodities and promote agricultural industrialization. Subsidized crop insurance for specific commodities, which was emphasized in the latest US Farm Bill, is simply another means of subsidizing agricultural industrialization. Subsidized crop insurance, particularly insurance that insures both yields and prices, reduces the economic risks associated with specializing in one or two crops, such as corn and soybeans, and promote large-scale industrial farming operations. All these programs should be deemphasized and eventually phased out. The only exception for crop-specific subsidies would be for production needed for domestic food security, which should be produced under production controls that prevent economic exploitation. Other government programs that incentivize expansion of farm size, such as subsidized farm credit and investment tax credits, should also be phased out over time.

While such a change in US farm programs may seem radical today a similar planned phase out was included in the 1995 US Farm Bill, the “Freedom to Farm Act.” Elimination of crop-specific subsidies has also been an important aspect of ongoing “free trade” negotiations. In addition, such a phase out would not appreciably affect most US family farmers. As indicated previously, 75 percent of all US government payments go to ten percent of farmers, who almost certainly manage mono-functional farms. These payments directly subsidize chemical-intensive, genetically modified, irrigated cropping operations and indirectly subsidize large-scale confinement animal feeding operations. More than 60 percent of US farmers received no government payments and thus are not dependent on continuation of commodity-based programs.[82]

Commodity-based programs should be phased out over time to allow a transition period for the few multifunctional family farms that have become dependent on government payments for supplemental income. The incremental increase in government funds saved in the process of phasing out subsidies for mono-functional farms could be used to facilitate the development of replacement sources of income for multifunctional family farms. Over the longer term, competitiveness must be restored to agricultural markets to ensure that multifunctional family farms receive fair market prices or economic value for their products. Corporate dominance of markets is currently common to all sectors of the global economy and will require more comprehensive changes than those available through agricultural policies. However, there would still be a need for government farm policies. Even the most effective markets will not ensure either food security or agricultural sustainability.

Future government farm programs should be focused on developing and sustaining multifunctional family farms. Farm families need not be rewarded economically for everything they must do for the good of society or the future of humanity. For example, soil and water conservation incentives to farmers should be cost-sharing programs. Farmers must be willing to share in ecological and social costs, along with consumers and taxpayers. Ultimately, food consumers in general, not just elite “foodies,” must be willing to share in the ecological and social costs of sustainable farming. The economic costs will be bearable and less than the ecological and social value of doing so. The purpose of farm programs should be to allow taxpayers to do collectively, through government, those things that cannot be done individually. Farmers and consumers must bear some of the costs of agricultural sustainability individually, but they also must share other costs collectively, as taxpayers.

Incentivize families, not farms. A comprehensive list of North American government policies needed to replace current industrial farm policies is clearly beyond the scope of this report – but not beyond the realm of possibility or practically. Some general proposals include basing subsidies on whole-farm income rather than production of specific commodities. The intent of such programs would be to remove current incentives to specialize in specific subsidized crops or commoditieschieve odities. The intent of such programs would be to licies is beyond the scope of this repor. Subsidized whole-farm revenue insurance could be provided to reduce economic risks for multifunctional family farms, with lower premiums available to reflect lower risks of more diversified farming operations. Lower insurance costs for diversified farms would discourage specialization and industrialization.

All farm subsidies should be contingent on the implementation of sustainable farming practices. Farms that choose not to participate in government programs to avoid this requirement should be regulated the same as any other industrial operation, including environmental and worker safety regulations. The animals in such operations should be treated as workers with appropriate standards for humane treatment. Mono-functional farms should not be able to externalize their social or ecological costs by imposing them on communities or societies.

Government payments should be linked to family size not farm size – people not production. Maximum payments could be adjusted to reflect the dependence of the family on farm income. The motivation for such limits would be to encourage more families to engage in agriculture, particularly in ways that create a sense of connectedness between the families and their farms. Farm programs should be designed to sustain families through periods of economic adversity rather than create dependencies on government payments. The payments could be linked to net farm income, increasing to levels necessary to support families during years of negative net farm income and decreasing to elimination as net farm income approaches median non-farm incomes for non-farm comparable families.

Government provision of basic health care, as is already available in Canada, should be made available to multifunctional farm families in the US and Mexico to remove a major obstacle to full-time family farming. Multifunctional farmers should also be provided with worker’s compensation during recovery from inevitable injuries and illnesses. “Fringe benefits” of multifunctional farm families, provided through farm programs, should be comparable to government- and corporate-provided fringe benefits to non-farm workers.

Reform use of farmland for the common good. History has proven that allowing markets to value and allocate the use of farmland will not provide domestic food security and most certainly will not ensure either food security or agricultural sustainability. Meeting these challenges will require comprehensive land reform policies. For example, specific parcels of naturally productive farmland could be identified and zoned for use to provide domestic food security and global agricultural sustainability. Enough land would need to be “permanently zoned” for food production to meet the basic needs of all people, including current and future generations.

This approach would be very different from the current practice of buying “development rights” and placing land in agricultural “land trusts.” Any speculative “development value” of land currently zoned for agriculture would be lost with comprehensive land reform. However, society has no responsibility to ensure the success of the current speculative ownership of farmland. Owners of good farmland currently zoned for higher-valued economic uses could be compensated for “down-zoning” to agriculture, funded by taxing away speculative gains in lands that are up-zoned to higher-valued uses. Profits from up-zoning are essentially grants from societies, as the owners of such land have done nothing productive to increase its value. Taxing away such profits would also remove any economic pressure to up-zone good farmland from agriculture to other uses. Prices of farmland would reflect the economic value of land in producing food, not prices inflated by land speculation.

Farmland not needed for domestic food security would also need to be farmed sustainably. This land could be farmed by larger commercial operations to produce food for export to food-deficient nations, giving them an economic incentive to increase the sustainable productivity of their land. Global markets would again be restricted to trade in domestic agricultural surpluses, not depended on to provide domestic food security.

The effect of land tenure policies that support agricultural sustainability would be to return most farmland to some sense of common property, or at least common rights, by ensuring the use of farmland for the common good. In places where farmland remains in common use, it should be retained in common use, with adequate incentives to ensure that it is managed multifunctionally for the common good of farm families and society. Government-owned farmland should be offered to multifunctional farmers at minimal or no cost to allow young families to get started in farming without large investments in land. Given the cultural history of the US and Canada, it might be more acceptable to allow young farm families to “homestead” public land. They would be given a reasonable period of time to turn it into a successful multifunctional farm to qualify for ownership of the land. They would need to be able to make an economic living while caring for the land and contributing to the food needs of their community.

Redirect public research and education. If publicly funded research and education is to fulfill its public mission by supporting domestic food security and agricultural sustainability, the existing ties between agribusiness corporations and public-funded research and educational institutions must be broken. The current justification for private-public partnerships in research and education is that public interests are best served through the marketplace. While this approach may have seemed reasonable at some time in the past, the evidence is now clear that the industrialization of the food system has failed to provide either food security or long-run agricultural sustainability. The public research and educational agenda must be redirected toward agricultural sustainability through multifunctionality rather than food security through mono-functional economic efficiency, by empowering farm families with information and technologies appropriate for sustainable farming.

Publicly funded research and education must give priority to on-farm research and with-farmer education. Farming in the future must be treated as a learned profession. In the words of Adam Smith: “no endeavor requires a greater variety of knowledge and experience than does farming, other than possibly the fine arts or liberal professions.”[83] Multifunctional farmers need good basic liberal educations but they also need a deep personal sense of connectedness with their farms and communities. Young farm families need to be provided with personal tutors and mentors in the person of experienced farm families or aging farmers who have developed a close working relationship with their own farms and communities. Government mentorships and internships would ensure that interns or apprentices were not treated as a source of low-cost labor but as an opportunity to pass knowledge and wisdom from one generation to the next.

Restore family farms to position of high esteem. In summary, agricultural policies, in North America and elsewhere, must be realigned to move beyond a commitment to domestic food security to agricultural sustainability. Each family farmer should be encouraged to produce food on the farm to meet at least some of the basic needs of the family, and equally important, to maintain a sense of personal connectedness with the earth. Communities, rural and urban, should be encouraged to meet more of their food needs by supporting local farm families who farm multifunctionally – adjusting diets seasonally to take advantage of the resources of local foodsheds.

Each nation should strive for domestic food security, first through local food systems, with local deficiencies met through trade among communities that have developed long-term, trusting relationships. Unavoidable long-term food deficits within nations should be resolved through long-term international trade agreements that are based on trust rather than economic expediency. International markets for agricultural products should be relegated to trade that is not essential to agricultural sustainability but adds to the variety of diets and the pleasures of eating.

The sustainability of food production, for the long-term benefit of all of the “world’s people,” can be and must be ensured by government policies that support a global network of local community-based food systems that support and are supported by multifunctional family farms. Only multifunctional farmers are endowed with the inherent potential to farm sustainably, and sustainable farms are essential to sustainable agriculture and sustainable food systems. Public policies thus must support a transition from mono- to multi-functionality. Family farms can and must return to their honored, almost sacred, position in the cultures of North America and the rest of the world.

All Regional Reports prepared for the International Year of the Family Farming are now available as FAO-UN Working Papers:

Regional Perspectives on Family Farming

http://www.ipc-undp.org/pub/eng/OP337_Regional_perspectives_of_family_farming.pdf

Family Farming in North America

http://www.ipc-undp.org/pub/eng/WP152_Family_farms_of_North_America.pdf

Family Farming in Europe and Central Asia

http://www.ipc-undp.org/pub/eng/WP153_Family_farming_in_Europe_and_Central_Asia.pdf

Family Farming in Near East and North Africa:

http://www.ipc-undp.org/pub/eng/WP151_Family_farming_in_the_near_East_and_North_Africa.pdf

Family farming in Latin America and the Caribbean:

http://www.ipc-undp.org/pub/eng/WP137_Family_Farming_in_Latin_America_and_the_Caribbean.pdf

Family farming in Asia and the Pacific

http://www.fao.org/3/a-i5530e.pdf

Family Farming in sub-Saharan Africa

http://www.fao.org/3/a-i6056e.pdf

End Notes

[i] This paper was prepared by John Ikerd, Professor Emeritus of Agricultural and Applied Economics, University of Missouri-Columbia. Jennifer Sumner of the University of Toronto, Spencer Wood of Kansas State University, and Lisa Griffith of the National Family Farm Coalition reviewed earlier drafts of the paper and suggested revisions. The author is grateful for their suggestions, but accepts full responsibility for the content of the paper, including errors of omission or commission, as well as for all conclusions and recommendations included in the paper.

[1] Robert Albritton, “Two Great Food Revolutions: The Domestication of Nature and the Transgression of Nature’s Limits” in Critical Perspectives in Food Studies, ed., Mustafa Koc, Jennifer Sumner, and Anthony Winson (Oxford England: Oxford University Press, 2012). Note: Section concerning Canadian rely heavily on this reference.

[2] Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations, (1776, New York: Prometheus Books, 1991), 83.

[3] UPA-FAO, “Dialogue on Family Farming in North America,” 2014, 10. http://www.upa.qc.ca/SiteWeb_UPA/documents/DCVS/UPADI44pages_trilingue_final_web.pdf (accessed September 15, 2014).

[4] Curtis Stofferahn, “Industrialized Farming and Its Relationship to Community Well-Being: an Update of the 2000 Report by Linda Lobao,” North Dakota, Office of Attorney General, September, 2006, http://www.und.edu/org/ndrural/Lobao%20&%20Stofferahn.pdf (accessed September 15, 2014).

[5] Gro Bruntland, ed. Our Common Future, The World Commission on Environment and Development (Oxford, England: Oxford University Press, 1987).

[6] Karl Polanyi, The Great Transformation; The Political and Economic Origins of our Time (Boston: Beacon Press, 1944, 1957).

[7] Edward Thompson, The Making of the English Working Class, (New York: Penguin Press, 1991). P 217.

[8] Albritton, Critical Perspectives in Food Studies.

[9] US Department of Agriculture, Agriculture in the Classroom, “Growing a Nation, The Story of American Agriculture,” http://www.agclassroom.org/gan/timeline/1860.htm (accessed September 15, 2014).

[10] Albritton, Critical Perspectives.

[11] USDA, “Growing a Nation,” http://www.agclassroom.org/gan/timeline/1880.htm (accessed September 15, 2014).

[12] Faculty of Agriculture and Food Science, University of Manitoba, “Sustainability of Canada’s Agri-Food System; a Prairie Perspective,” International Institute of Sustainable Development, Winnipeg, Canada, 1994, 20. http://www.iisd.org/pdf/agrifood.pdf (accessed September 15, 2014).

[13] Faculty of Agriculture and Food Science, “Sustainability of Canada’s Agri-Food System,” 20.

[14] USDA, “Growing a Nation,” http://www.agclassroom.org/gan/timeline/1920.htm (accessed September 15, 2014).

[15] Statistics Canada, “A statistical portrait of agriculture, Canada and provinces: census years 1921 to 2006,” http://www.statcan.gc.ca/pub/95-632-x/2007000/t/4185570-eng.htm (accessed September 15, 2014).

[16] Ian MacPherson, Each for All: A History of the Co-operative Movement in English Canada, 1900-1945 (Toronto: The Macmillan Company of Canada Limited, 1979), 12.

[17] “Rochdale Principles,” in Wikipedia, The Free Encyclopedia, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Rochdale_Principles (accessed September 15, 2014).

[18] Ian MacPherson, A Century of Co-operation (Ottawa: The Canadian Co-operative Association, 2009) 28.

[19] USDA, “Growing a Nation,” http://www.agclassroom.org/gan/timeline/1970.htm (accessed September 15, 2014).

[20] Statistics Canada, “A statistical portrait of agriculture.”.

[21] Leopold Center for Sustainable Agriculture, Iowa State University, “Why Worry About Agriculture of the Middle,” http://www.leopold.iastate.edu/pubs-and-papers/2004-06-agriculture-middle (accessed September 15, 2014).

[22] Ricardo Améndola, Epigmenio Castillo & Pedro A. Martínez, “Country/Pastures Forage/Resource Profiles, Mexico,” http://www.fao.org/ag/AGP/AGPC/doc/Counprof/Mexico/Mexico.htm (accessed September 15, 2014).

[23] Améndola, Castillo & Martínez, “Country/Pastures Forage/Resource Profiles, Mexico.”

[24] “Mexico – Agriculture,” in Nations Encyclopedia, http://www.country-data.com/cgi-bin/query/r-8742.html (accessed September 15, 2014).

[25] Environmental Working Group, “EWG Farm Subsidy Database, United States Summary,” http://farm.ewg.org/region.php?fips=00000 (accessed September 15, 2014).

[26] Albritton, Critical Perspectives.

[27] United States Environmental Protection Agency, “Fuels and Fuel Additives Renewable Fuels Standards,” http://www.epa.gov/otaq/fuels/renewablefuels/ (accessed September 15, 2014).

[28] United States Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, “Bioenergy,” http://www.ers.usda.gov/topics/farm-economy/bioenergy/findings.aspx#.VBXrWPldV8E (accessed September 15, 2014).

[29] Nettie Wiebe, “Crisis in the Food System: the Farm Crisis,” in Critical Perspectives in Food Studies.

[30] Via Campesina, “The Right to Produce and Access to Land” 1996. www.viacampesina.org (accessed September 15, 2014).

[31] Nettie Wiebe, “Crisis in the Food System,in Critical Perspectives.

[32] Timothy Wise, “Agricultural Dumping Under NAFTA: Estimating the Costs of U.S. Agricultural Policies to Mexican Producers,” Woodrow Wilson International Center for Scholars, 2010,

http://www.ase.tufts.edu/gdae/Pubs/rp/AgricDumpingWoodrowWilsonCenter.pdf .

[33] Gisele Henriques and Raj Patel, "NAFTA, Corn, and Mexico’s Agricultural Trade Liberalization," Interhemispheric Resource Center, Feb. 13, 2004, 6. http://dspace.africaportal.org/jspui/bitstream/123456789/113/1/NAFTA%20Corn%20and%20Mexicos%20Agricultural%20Trade%20Liberalization.pdf?1 (accessed September 15, 2014).

[34] Colombia and Mexico Country Management Unit, Latin America and the Caribbean Region, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Division, “Poverty in Mexico: An Assessment of Conditions, Trends and Government Strategy, World Bank Report No. 28612-ME, June 2004. http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/EXTPOVERTY/EXTPA/0,,contentMDK:20269019~menuPK:443285~pagePK:148956~piPK:216618~theSitePK:430367,00.html (accessed September 15, 2014).

[35] UPA-FAO, “Dialogue on Family Farming,” 10.

[36] UPA-FAO, “Dialogue on Family Farming,” 10.

[37] U.S. Department of Agriculture, NASS, 2007 Census of Agriculture; INEGI, Estados Unidos Mexicanos, Censo Agropecuario 2007; Statistics Canada, 2006 Census of Agriculture, “Average Age of Principal Farm Operators, Canada, United States, and Mexico,” http://webpage.siap.gob.mx/opt/mapas/Map_Edadpromedio_en.pdf (accessed September 15, 2014).

[38]Kate Dean, Washington Farm Link, “Farmland Changing Hands,” November 2011, http://www.cascadeharvest.org/files/u1/Farmland_Changing_Hands_0.pdf (accessed September 15, 2014).

[39] John E Ikerd., “Local Food: Revolution and Reality,” Journal of Agricultural and Food Information, Volume. 12, Number 1, 2011, 49-57.

[40] Jennifer Sumner, J. J. McMurtry, and Hannah Renglich,“Leveraging the local: Cooperative food systems and the Local Organic Food Co-ops Network in Ontario, Canada” Journal of Agriculture, Food Systems, and Community Development Volume 4, Issue 3 / Spring 2014, 49. www.AgDevJournal.com (accessed September 15, 2014).

[41] International Assessment of Agricultural Knowledge, Science, and Technology for Development, Agriculture at a Crossroads, Global Report, (Washington DC: Island Press, 2009). http://www.unep.org/dewa/agassessment/reports/IAASTD/EN/Agriculture%20at%20a%20Crossroads_Global%20Report%20%28English%29.pdf .

[42] “Farmers,”, http://en.wiktionary.org/wiki/farmer, (accessed September 15,2014).

[43] “Farm,” from Wikionary, Open Content Dictionary; cites The Century Dictionary and Cyclopedia; Wedgwood, Atkinson, A dictionary of English etymology; and Mantello, Rigg, Medieval Latin: an introduction and bibliographical guide, 11.3, http://en.wiktionary.org/wiki/farm , (accessed September 15, 2014).

[44] IAASTD: Agriculture at a Crossroads, 2.

[45] John Ikerd, The Essentials of Economic Sustainability, (Bloomfield, CT: Kumarian Press, 2012. Chapter 1.

[46] National Chicken Council, “Vertical Integration,” http://www.nationalchickencouncil.org/industry-issues/vertical-integration/ (accessed September 15, 2014).

[47] William D. McBride and Nigel Key, “U.S. Hog Production From 1992 to 2009: Technology, Restructuring, and

Productivity Growth,” USDA, ERS. http://www.ers.usda.gov/publications/err-economic-research-report/err158.aspx#.U-jy9fldV8E (accessed September 15, 2014).

[48] Economic Research Service, US Department of Agriculture, “Adoption of Genetically Engineered Crops in the US,” http://www.ers.usda.gov/data-products/adoption-of-genetically-engineered-crops-in-the-us/recent-trends-in-ge-adoption.aspx#.U-jzjPldV8E (accessed September 15, 2014).

[49] Michael Duffy, “Economies of Size in Production Agriculture,” Journal of Hunger Environmental Nutrition, July 2009; 4(3-4): 375–392. http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pmc/articles/PMC3489134/ .(Accessed, October 10, 2014)

[50] David and Marcia Pimentel, Food, Energy, and Society (Niwot, CO: University Press of Colorado), 1996.

[51] Judith S. Soule and John K. Piper, Farming in Nature’s Image, An Ecological Approach to Agriculture, (Washingtion, DC: Island Press, 1992).

[52] Fred Kirschenmann, Cultivating an Ecological Conscience, (Berkeley, CA: Counterpoint, 2010).

[53] Dana Cordell and Jan-Olof Drangert, and Stuart White, (May 2009). "The story of phosphorus: Global food security and food for thought". Global Environmental Change (Elsevier) 19 (2): 292–305.

Also, Natasha Gilbert, (8 October 2009). "The disappearing nutrient". Nature 461: 716–718.

[54]“Greenhouse gas”, in Wikipedia, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Greenhouse_gas and “Climate Change and Agriculture,” http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Climate_change_and_agriculture (accessed September 15, 2014).

[55] Alisha Coleman-Jensen, Christian Gregory, and Anita Singh, “Household Food Security in the U.S. in 2013,” Economic Research Report No 173, September 2014. http://www.ers.usda.gov/media/1565415/err173.pdf (accessed September 15, 2014)

[56] CBC News, “One in eight Canadian families struggle to put food on tables,” July 2013, http://www.cbc.ca/news/canada/new-brunswick/1-in-8-canadian-families-struggle-to-put-food-on-table-study-says-1.1346620 (accessed September 15, 2014).

[57] Rand Corporation, “Cost of Treatment for Obesity-Related Medical Problems Growing Dramatically,” Rand Corporation, http://www.rand.org/news/press/2004/03/09.html . (accessed September 15, 2014).

[58] CMS.gov, Center for Medical and Health Services, NHE Fact Sheet, https://www.cms.gov/NationalHealthExpendData/25_NHE_Fact_Sheet.asp (accessed September 15, 2014).

[59] Donald Davis, Melvin Epp, and Hugh Riordan, 2004,“Changes in USDA Food Composition Data for 43 Garden Crops, 1950 to 1999” Journal of American College of Nutrition, 23:669-682. Bob Smith, 1993, Organic Foods vs Supermarket Foods: Element Levels, Journal of Applied Nutrition, 45:35-39. W.M. Jarrell and R.B. Beverly, 1981, “The Dilution Effect in Plant Nutrient Studies,” Advances in Agronomy, 34:197–224.

[60] Stacia Nordin and Kristof Nordin, “Green Revolution Fails,” Never Ending Food: A Permaculture Nutrition Training Manual available from the authors (2000), http://www.neverendingfood.org/articles/how-the-green-revolution-has-failed-to-feed-us/ (accessed September 15, 2014).

[61] Vandana Shiv, “The Green Revolution in the Punjab,” The Ecologist, Vol. 21, No. 2, March-April 1991, http://livingheritage.org/green-revolution.htm (accessed September 15, 2014).

[62] United Nations Environmental Program, Towards a Green Economy: Pathways to Sustainable Development and Poverty Eradication, 2010, www.unep.org/greeneconomy (accessed September 15, 2014).

[63] Miguel Alteri, Agroecology, “Small Farms, and Food Sovereignty,” Monthly Review, Vol. 61, Issue 3, July/August, 2009. http://monthlyreview.org/2009/07/01/agroecology-small-farms-and-food-sovereignty (accessed September 15, 2014).

[64] Chuck Francis, Multiple Cropping Systems (New York: MacMillan, 1986).

[65] United Nations Environment Programme, Organic agriculture and food security in Africa, UNEP-UNCTAD Capacity-building Task Force, on Trade, Environment and Development ,New York and Geneva, 2008 http://unctad.org/en/docs/ditcted200715_en.pdf (accessed September 15, 2014).

[66] Peter Rosset, The Case for Small Farms, an interview, Multinational Monitor, July/August 2000, Vol. 21, Numbers 7 & 8, http://www.multinationalmonitor.org/mm2000/00july-aug/interview.html (accessed September 15, 2014).

[67] L. E. Drinkwater, Wagoner, P. & Sarrantonio, M. “Legume-based cropping systems have reduced carbon and nitrogen losses.” Nature 396, 1998, 262–265.

[68] Rodale Institute, “The Farming Systems Trials; Celebrating 30 years,” 2012, http://rodaleinstitute.org/assets/FSTbooklet.pdf (accessed September 15, 2014).

[69] Verena Seufert, Navin Ramankutty, and Jonathan A. Foley, “Comparing the yields of organic and conventional agriculture,” Nature, Number 485, May 10, 2012, 229–232, http://www.nature.com/nature/journal/v485/n7397/abs/nature11069.html .(accessed September 15, 2014).

[70] Parke Wilde, “Crop yields are only part of the organic vs. conventional farming debate,” Grist, May 2012. http://grist.org/organic-food/crop-yields-are-only-part-of-the-organic-vs-conventional-farming-debate/ (accessed September 15, 2014).

[71] IAASTD, Agriculture at a Crossroads.

[72] John Ikerd, Crisis and Opportunity; Sustainability in American Agriculture, (Lincoln NE; University of Nebraska Press, 2008).

[73] UPA-FAO, “Dialogue on Family Farming,” 10.

[74] James MacDonald, “Family Farming in the U.S.,” Economic Research Service, USDA, March 2014, http://www.ers.usda.gov/amber-waves/2014-march/family-farming-in-the-united-states.aspx#.U_NzSvldV8E (accessed September 15, 2014).

[75] Government of Saskatchewan, Think Ag, “Definitions of Farm and Farmer,” http://www.agriculture.gov.sk.ca/Default.aspx?DN=3dd4c88d-3412-486d-8d02-292b5b4d5d30 (accessed September 15, 2014).

[76] Statistics Canada, “2011 Census of Agriculture, Chapter 2,” http://www.statcan.gc.ca/pub/95-640-x/2012002/02-eng.htm (accessed September 15, 2014).

[77] FAO Regional Office for Latin America and the Caribbean, “Family Farm Observatory,” http://www.rlc.fao.org/en/about-fao/regional-priorities/family-farming/baf/2013-06/ffo/ (accessed September 15, 2014).

[78] Douglas H. Constance and William D. Heffernan, “The Global Poultry Agro/Food Complex,” International Journal of Sociology of Agriculture and Food, Volume 1 (1991), 126-142

[79] UPA-FAO, “Dialogue on Family Farming,” 21.

[80] FAO, “Dialogue of Family Farming,” 21.

[81] UPA-FAO, “Dialogue,” 21.

[82] Environmental Working Group, http://farm.ewg.org/region.php?fips=00000 (September 15, 2014).

[83] Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations, (1776, New York: Prometheus Books, 1991) 83.